Master Thesis Digital Banking & Financial Technology



Yüklə 0,77 Mb.
Pdf görüntüsü
səhifə11/18
tarix27.12.2023
ölçüsü0,77 Mb.
#200146
1   ...   7   8   9   10   11   12   13   14   ...   18
Anastasiou MDE2003

The Future of Finance

[online] Available at: 
https://www.betandbetter.com/photos_forum/1425585417.pdf

Ogunode, O.A. and Akintoye, R.I. (2023). Financial Technologies and Financial 
Inclusion in Emerging Economies: Perspectives from Nigeria. 
Asian Journal of 
Economics, Business and Accounting
, pp.38
–54. doi:10.9734/ajeba/2023/v23i1915. 
Reuters (2016). Singapore to update electronic payment regulations in fintech drive. 
Reuters
. [online] 19 Aug. Available at: 
https://www.reuters.com/article/singapore-
cenbank-fintech-idUSL3N1B01II [Accessed 27 Jan. 2023].
Sullivan, T. (2022). 
Financial inclusion: How fintech expands access to all
. [online] 
Plaid. Available at: 
https://plaid.com/resources/fintech/financial-inclusion/.
Walchek, S. (2015). 
The Unbundling Of Finance
. [online] TechCrunch. Available at: 
https://techcrunch.com/2015/05/29/the-unbundling-of-finance/.
Yang, S. (2015). 
Why Wall Street is pouring money into companies that want to eat 
its 
lunch

[online] 
Business 
Insider. 
Available 
at: 
https://www.businessinsider.com/wall-street-invests-in-fintech-startups-2015-3 
[Accessed 27 Jan. 2023]. 
Zavolokina, L., Dolata, M. and Schwabe, G. (2016). 
FinTech 
– What’s in a Name?
[online] www.zora.uzh.ch. doi:10.5167/uzh-126806. 


51 
Chapter 4: Reform of the European banking system 
4.1. The characteristics of the existing framework 
The debate on how to improve the rules and procedures for dealing with bank 
failures in the European banking union began a few years ago, but gained 
momentum in 2017 when two major banks 
– both of which fell under the purview of 
the Single Supervisory Mechanism (SSM) and the Single Resolution Board (SRB) 
– 
failed. These incidents demonstrated how challenging it can be for the existing laws 
to permit the orderly market exit of various sorts of institutions whose failure could 
cause systemic disruption. It is somewhat paradoxical that these difficulties have 
become so pronounced in the EU, as this is arguably the jurisdiction that has 
modernized its crisis management framework the most by adopting the new 
international standards on bank resolution (the FSB Key Attributes) in a timely, 
thorough, and stringent manner (Restoy, 2022). 
The current role of ECB and ESCB is to (Cambis, n.d.): 

Serve European Commission’s targets 

Remove fragmentation and secure max benefit for EU citizens and firms 

Enhance digital operation resilience framework 
The FSB Core Characteristics were one of the most significant regulatory 
measures implemented by the worldwide community in the wake of the Great 
Financial Crisis (GFC) to lessen the likelihood and economic effect of financial crises. 
They intended to implement a bank resolution mechanism that would aid in 
maintaining the essential functions of failing systemic institutions without requiring a 
significant outlay of public resources. Based on its own experiences during the global 
financial crisis, the EU had a clear incentive to adopt the new resolution system 
(Buch, Bundesbank and Dages, 2018). Europe was the region hardest damaged by 
the global financial crisis, necessitating substantial public aid. Between 2008 and 
2014, the net cost to European governments of sustaining financial institutions 
exceeded €200 billion (European Union, 2020).


52 
Image 

Overview 
of 
main 
causes 
of 
the 
EU 
financial 
crisis 
https://www.eca.europa.eu/lists/ecadocuments/rw20_05/rw_financial_crisis_prevention_en.pdf
  
This resulted in the adoption of procyclical fiscal austerity programs, which 
exacerbated the economic recession that followed the start of the crisis. Moreover, 
this connection between the weaknesses of banks and the need for public support 
sparked a destabilizing spiral between financial and sovereign risk that spawned 
redenomination risks, ultimately endangering the very existence of the European 


53 
monetary union. To preserve both the social cohesion within member countries and 
the resiliency of the European integration project, it was deemed necessary for 
Europe to develop crisis management tools that could reduce reliance on public 
funds to safeguard financial stability, in accordance with the FSB's Key Attributes
(European Union, 2020). 
In response, European authorities established a single resolution mechanism 
(SRM) in 2014 as part of the banking union initiative. In legal parlance, the SRM 
creates rules, tools, and procedures for addressing the failure of systemic institutions 
in the banking union, or those that meet public interest criteria. These restrictions 
include an effective ban on government bailouts and a predominance of creditor bail-
ins to preserve the essential activities of failing institutions. In addition, the new 
framework envisages the centralisation of resolution decisions within a European 
agency (the SRB) and the establishment of an industry-contributed mutualised fund 
(the Single Resolution Fund, SRF) (EUR-Lex, 2014, consolidated 2022). This fund 
may be utilized to support resolution actions, but only if a substantial number of 
creditors' claims have been bailed in. According with these minimal bail-in standards, 
banks are ordinarily required to issue huge quantities of financial instruments that 
could become loss-absorbing at the time of insolvency (the minimum requirement for 
own funds and eligible liabilities, MREL) (Single Resolution Board, 2022a). 
Image 7 Internal MREL for an expanded scope of non-resolution entities 
Expanding the number of subsidiaries for whom the SRB will establish an 
internal MREL. Entities providing important functions and/or those surpassing the 32% 
criterion of the resolution group's total risk exposure amount, or leverage exposure, 


54 
or total operational income (the previous requirement was 43%), or those with total 
assets exceeding EUR 10bn are included in the scope. They are known as RLEs. 
Notably, entities delivering vital functions are included in the definition of RLEs even 
if their size falls below the threshold. In addition, the SRB establishes internal MREL 
for intermediate entities, which are defined as subsidiaries of resolution entities that 
are the parent entities of at least one RLE. In accordance with the SRB's guideline on 
the scope of LDR reporting, the above-mentioned companies are required to submit 
an LDR to guarantee that the financial data required to calculate MREL is accessible. 
As considered appropriate in future cycles, the SRB will reevaluate the extent of 
subsidiaries with internal MREL (Single Resolution Board, 2022a). 
The regulations governing the SRM represent a strict adaptation of the FSB 
Core Characteristics. No other jurisdiction has arguably put more specific and 
stringent restrictions on the use of foreign funding (public or private) to facilitate 
resolution. In addition, it is uncommon for authorities outside the EU to require banks 
(and not just internationally systemic ones) to meet MREL-type obligations. Again, 
the severity of these limits is essentially a political reaction to recent events and the 
particular institutional constraints created by the multinational nature of the European 
banking union (Arda & Dobler, 2022). 
Image 8 European institutions for financial supervision and resolution in a Banking Union 
While the design of the EU resolution mechanism is internally coherent, it 
does not provide a robust blueprint for addressing the failure of a significant portion 
of banking union institutions. In this regard, it is crucial to underline that the common 
resolution framework coexists alongside a constellation of domestic insolvency 
regimes enshrined in national law that have not altered significantly in recent years. 
When failing institutions do not meet the required resolution criteria relating to the 
public interest, national regimes 
– which frequently involve the administration of 
court-based general insolvency proceedings 
– are nonetheless implemented. 
Intriguingly, the availability of public assistance during insolvency (in the form of 
liquidation aid) is, on average, far less constrained than during resolution. 


55 
The Single Resolution Mechanism is a component of the European Banking 
Union's broader structure. Image 8 depicts the steps of decision-making and the 
relevant bodies in this new emerging European governance structure. The European 
Central Bank (ECB) assumes the role of supervisor and lender of last resort for the 
European financial sector, while the European Commission retains its regulatory 
authority. If this level fails to fix difficulties, resolution is the next step (i.e. a single 
resolution mechanism). Schoenmaker and Gros (2012) advocate for the 
establishment of an independent European Deposit Insurance and Resolution 
Authority (EDIRA) that would be responsible for this phase. The third component of 
the governance structure is the fiscal backstop. The European Stability Mechanism 
(ESM) was established to serve as a fiscal safety net for member nations, but it may 
also serve as a fiscal safety net for the banking systems of member countries 
experiencing financial trouble. Hence, the arrow for the fiscal backstop is reversed in 
Image 8. Given the necessity for a fiscal backstop, the new SRM (in the form of an 
EDIRA) must work closely with the ESM. Notwithstanding this, it is crucial to preserve 
the independence of the resolution authority, as the ESM is governed by the 
ministries of finance (Beck, Gros and Schoenmaker, 2013). 
Image 9 table of vulnerabilities 
https://www.bankingsupervision.europa.eu/ecb/pub/ra/html/ssm.ra2021~edbbea1f8f.en.html
 


56 
Bail-in policies improve market discipline by guaranteeing that the agents 
responsible for bank distress are held accountable by removing the bank's managers 
and lowering shareholder and creditor rights. Shareholders and creditors are held 
accountable for monitoring the bank and limiting excessive risk-taking, specifically 
through the pricing of shares and debt. Prior to the crisis, market discipline was 
failing due to the too big to fail subsidy on the debt of giant banks; troubled banks 
were not compelled to pay higher borrowing costs. In addition, the capital infusions 
decreased the losses owners and creditors of bailed-out banks incurred during the 
crisis. Bail-ins would save the bank from failure, but shareholders and creditors would 
be responsible for losses and costs associated with the bail-in. The prices of stocks 
and bonds should be adjusted to reflect these anticipated losses (Meehl, 2022).
Owing to the change in payoffs to shareholders and creditors in the event of a 
bail-in, the equilibrium values of shares and debt under this new regime should differ 
from those under the bailout regime. Banks' exit, entry, risk-taking, and debt-to-equity 
financing decisions could be affected by a shift in prices. For instance, the greater 
cost of borrowing for banks following the abolition of bailouts could lead to a 
reduction in investment and lending, which could inadvertently affect consumers. In 
addition, a prospective loss of shares due to a bail-in may discourage shareholders 
from investing in a new bank, so limiting the industry's growth. While the bailing-in of 
a bank may preserve its services for some customers, decreasing entry may result in 
a decline in banking services generally. Hence, the consequences of this new policy 
on consumers are unknown, and a structural model is required to compare 
equilibrium conditions under each policy. A few bail-ins have occurred in the EU thus 
far, although these resolutions occurred before the Financial Recovery and 
Resolution Regulation was finalized. In conducting these bail-ins, there was no single 
policy to follow, and many of them were only partial bail-ins that also included bailout 
elements. In addition, it is unknown whether banks and their creditors anticipated 
bail-ins. Consequently, it is impractical to predict how banks' decisions might alter 
under a "bail-in regime" using EU banking data collected after the financial crisis and 
before to the finalization of Banking Recovery and Resolution Directive (Meehl, 2022). 
If bail-in becomes a crucial component of contemplated resolution procedures, 
the current structure is ineffective for dealing with the failure of banks whose liabilities 
cannot be utilised for loss absorption or recapitalization without causing a major 
disturbance. This describes medium-sized banks that are primarily funded by 
deposits. These institutions are often too large to be subject to traditional insolvency 
liquidation procedures, but too small and inexperienced to issue the substantial sums 


57 
of bail-in-able debt (such as subordinated bonds) required for resolution. In the 
absence of those instruments on these banks' balance sheets, authorities would not 
be able to recapitalise the institutions by making use of internal funds or by gaining 
access to the resolution funds as the minimal bail-in conditions for the latter would 
not be met (Restoy, 2016). 
Authorities have handled the issues provided by the failure of mid-sized 
banks by utilizing national insolvency procedures and utilizing public funds to enable 
a smooth withdrawal from the market. This has necessitated delicacy in the 
evaluation of the systemic consequences of bank collapses. In specifically, in order 
to be subject to national insolvency, those failures have to fail the public interest test 
for resolution. To justify the use of taxpayer cash, these projects have to be judged 
as having a negative impact on the economic or financial system (Restoy, Vrbaski 
and Walters, 2020). 
This strategy is suboptimal. It implies, rather paradoxically, that in order to 
activate the necessary support to prevent systemic stress, authorities must avoid 
employing the framework specifically created to deal with systemic bank crises 
(resolution) and instead deploy the regime intended for less significant institutions 
(insolvency) (European Commission, 2014). Moreover, the extensive use of national 
insolvency regimes 
– funded entirely with domestic resources – represents a 
departure from the principles that inspired the creation of the banking union, namely 
the urgent need to sever the destabilizing link between domestic financial risks and 
the sovereign. It would necessitate the renationalization of bank failure management 
and, thus, the renationalization of bank risks. 
Prior to addressing the flaws of the current framework for crisis management 
in the banking union, greater harmonization of domestic insolvency procedures is 
required. While a comprehensive common insolvency framework appears politically 
unfeasible at this time, there should be room to further harmonise those domestic 
solutions that have the greatest potential to cause friction with the common resolution 
scheme. Moreover, when facing the failure of mid-sized banks, it is necessary to 
avoid the paradoxical choice between open bank bail-in under resolution and 
piecemeal liquidation under insolvency, as both approaches have the potential to 
destabilize the financial system. Additionally, relying on public assistance during 
insolvency cannot be regarded to be a viable solution to this situation (Garicano, 
2020). 
Facilitating 
sale-of-business 
(SoB) 
(or 
purchase-and-assumption) 
transactions to arrange the orderly exit of failing banks is a potentially effective 
strategy for tackling the aforementioned difficulties. These strategies 
– in which 


58 
deposits and other sensitive liabilities of failing banks are transferred to stronger 
institutions 
– have been employed successfully in other jurisdictions, such as the 
United States, for a number of years but cannot be easily implemented in the 
European context at this time (FDIC, 2013). Clearly, the success of SoB tactics is 
contingent upon the presence of a suitable customer. This is highly dependent on the 
value of the failing bank's transferable assets and the availability of external finance 
to compensate buyers for assuming failing banks' deposits if, as is frequently the 
case, the available assets are insufficient. 
It is possible to raise the amount of assets that can be transferred by forcing 
medium-sized banks to keep, as a counterpart, liabilities that can be written off or 
converted into capital as the banks fail. Hence, a correctly calibrated MREL could 
facilitate the implementation of transfer schemes. Yet, given the restricted ability of 
mid-sized banks to perpetually issue and reimburse bail-in-eligible liabilities, external 
funds should be available to compensate buyers. In certain jurisdictions, the deposit 
guarantee scheme (DGS) can offer this external money. However, DGS funding is 
often constrained to a financial ceiling: it is only accessible if the anticipated cost of 
the intervention is less than the cost of paying out deposits in liquidation (Restoy, 
2022). 
In the case of the EU, DGS assistance for SoB transactions is severely 
constrained (if not rendered irrelevant) by legal rules that place DGS claims above 
uncovered deposits in the hierarchy of creditors. This "super-preference" of DGS 
claims shields them from incurring liquidation losses. The conclusion is that 
European DGS are unable to enable SoB transactions, even though they would 
prevent a potentially disruptive and value-destroying piecemeal liquidation (European 
Banking Authority, 2019). Similarly, the SRF is not an appropriate source of capital to 
enable SoB transactions for mid-sized banks under the current system. The SRF is 
only available to failing institutions that satisfy the public interest criteria for resolution 
and only after a substantial bail-in of creditors has been implemented. As previously 
noted, it will frequently be extremely challenging for mid-sized banks to achieve these 
standards (Restoy, 2021). 
Thus, the viability of SoB transactions necessitates substantial modifications 
to the current structure to permit adequate coverage of their finance requirements. 
One alternative is to loosen the limit on the use of DGS money to assist transfer 
transactions, which is now tied to the expenses associated with payout deposits in 
liquidation (European Commission, 2012). But, any action in this area must retain the 
DGS's ability to fulfill its primary mission, which is to safeguard insured deposits. 
Whether the existing super-priority of DGS claims in Europe is justified on public 


59 
policy grounds is a topic of controversy. It might be claimed that there is no clear 
policy justification for DGS claims to take precedence over uncovered deposits. In 
fact, the super-preference of DGS claims implies that individuals holding deposits in 
excess of the maximum amount insured by the DGS are less protected in insolvency 
than the indirect positions held by DGS-affiliated banks in relation to the failing 
organization.
In addition, following the example of other countries, such as the United 
States, and replacing the super-preferred of DGS claims with a general deposit 
preference rule could assist in mitigating risks of bank runs, hence preserving 
financial stability. This alternative preference rule would automatically loosen the 
current restriction on the use of DGS money to support SoB transactions, without 
jeopardizing the DGS's primary objectives (Mecatti, 2020). 
The SRF could serve as an alternate source of financing. This would 
necessitate relaxing the current minimum bail-in requirements for the usage of these 
resources. In fact, there appears to be a compelling case for considering that the 
conditions for the SRF to facilitate an orderly market exit of failing banks, such as 
through a SoB transaction, should be less stringent than those imposed to ensure 
that the failing bank could continue operating and performing essential functions. 
Following a SoB resolution method, it is conceivable that banks (usually medium-
sized) might be subject to less stringent minimum bail-in criteria. Note that while 
funds from the SRF would only be available for banks submitted to resolution, 
funding from the DGS could support bank failures regardless of whether the public 
interest requirement is met (Single Resolution Board, 2022b). 
4.2. Crisis management for EU banks 
The creation of a crisis management framework for failing or likely-to-fail 
institutions is a crucial step towards enhancing the resilience of the financial sector. 
In the absence of a proper structure to handle the process in an orderly manner, 
bank failures can have enormous disruptive impacts on the economy. In order to 
address these concerns, the EU has devised a comprehensive crisis management 
framework for banks, which consists of the Banking Recovery and Resolution 
Directive and the Single Resolution Mechanism Regulation (European Union, 2020). 
Four essential steps comprise the crisis management framework for banks 
(see Image 10). In the preparatory phase, supervisors watch banks to detect any 


60 
impending crises as soon as possible. In addition, resolution authorities guarantee 
that all banks are resolvable and that all resolution plans are current. Supervisors 
may employ early intervention methods if a bank encounters difficulty. Yet, if the 
situation worsens, regulators or resolution authorities must proclaim the bank to be 
failing or likely to fail (FOLTF). After determining if resolution is required, appropriate, 
and in the public interest, resolution authorities must devise a resolution strategy. If 
resolution is not in the public's best interest, the bank is liquidated in accordance with 
national insolvency proceedings (European Union, 2020). 
Image 
10 
Four 
phases 
of 
crisis 
management 
for 
EU 
banks 
https://www.eca.europa.eu/lists/ecadocuments/rw20_05/rw_financial_crisis_prevention_en.pdf
  
The new resolution framework includes the write-down and conversion of 
capital instruments tool and the bail-in tool, which are designed to shift the loss 
burden from taxpayers to shareholders and creditors (who would have benefited from 
any profits). It also contains three resolution tools: "sale of business," "bridge 
institution," and "asset separation." To defend the right to private property, the "no-
creditor-worse-off" concept ensures that under national insolvency laws, no 
shareholder or creditor is treated less favorably in resolution than in liquidation 
(European Union, 2020). 
The requirement that banks keep a sufficient level of loss-absorbing capacity 
in the form of the minimum requirement for own funds and eligible liabilities (MREL) 
is a crucial element for ensuring resolvability, as it enables the use of the bail-in tool. 
The MREL comprises of the required capital and bail-in-eligible liabilities, which could 
be utilized to recapitalize the bank (Single Resolution Board, 2017). The identification 
and elimination of substantive barriers to resolution is another crucial step. In addition 
to the bail-in mechanism, the SRF, the required Deposit Guarantee Schemes, and 
the proposed EDIS supplement the resolution framework to permit banks to fail in an 


61 
orderly way without resorting to public bailouts, which might potentially start the 
doomsday loop. They are sponsored in advance by the industry (European Union, 
2020). 
All of the aforementioned resolution steps are intended to break the 
doomsday loop and prevent banks from becoming "too big to fail." The Banks 
Recovery and Resolution Directive stipulates that public funds may only be utilized 
"in the most exceptional circumstances of a systemic crisis, as a last option," and 
under stringent restrictions and requirements. Both liquidation and resolution must 
adhere to State aid regulations anytime public funds, including the SRF, are 
employed. State aid regulations prohibit any use of public funding that could impair 
internal market competition. Throughout and after the financial crisis, the 
Commission issued a number of interpretative Communications on the application of 
State assistance rules. It still applies the Banking Communication from 2013 
(European Commision, 2013). 
The Bank Recovery and Resolution Directive (BRRD) ushered in a new crisis 
management system for the European Union in 2015. (EU). The decree was 
intended to address the "too-big-to-fail" problem and eliminate the need for public 
bailouts in the case of bank collapses. In accordance with the Key Attributes of 
Effective Resolution Regimes for Financial Institutions published by the FSB in the 
wake of the global financial crisis of 2007-08, the focus of this reform was on 
systemically important banks, i.e., those banks whose failure would likely threaten 
financial stability and have severe repercussions for the domestic and international 
real economy. During the global financial crisis, as as as during prior crises, the 
bailout of these institutions was extremely expensive for governments and, ultimately, 
taxpayers. Hence, the answer envisioned on a worldwide scale was to internalize the 
losses through the deployment of "bail-in," the principal instrument supporting the 
new resolution structure. By moving the cost of the financial crisis from taxpayers to 
investors and creditors, the framework aimed to decrease moral hazard and level the 
playing field between larger and smaller banks by eliminating the implicit subsidies 
enjoyed by the former. However, less attention has been paid to banks that are not 
systemic, especially the vast majority of EU banks, which are small and medium-
sized (Cunliffe, 2016).
Nonetheless, small and medium-sized banks contribute significantly to the 
economy's finance. In the euro area, smaller banks own 19% of the banking sector's 
total assets; in some countries, such as Austria, Germany, Ireland, and Luxembourg, 
this proportion exceeds 33% (European Central Bank, 2020). In addition, small and 
medium-sized institutions may suffer the most from the pandemic's economic 


62 
repercussions. Could this generate an unprecedented "too-many-to-fail" dilemma that 
is challenging to solve within the existing framework? A recent Bank of Italy analysis 
reveals that the impact of the pandemic on Italian banks' credit risk exposure could 
be greater for smaller institutions than for larger ones, due to the disparate sectoral 
compositions of their loan portfolios (Banca d'Italia, 2020). The national insolvency 
proceedings of EU member states are extremely diverse. Some nations, for instance, 
have special insolvency regimes that apply primarily to banks, while others have 
standard bankruptcy regimes that apply to all types of businesses; some countries 
have judicial-based frameworks while others implement administrative-based 
frameworks. This diversity causes an issue with equal playing fields, as creditors and 
depositors may be handled differently within the Union, thereby fostering financial 
fragmentation (Visco, 2021). 
The primary goal of any change of the current system should be to prevent 
disorderly, fragmented liquidations and the resultant wasteful destruction of assets. In 
Europe, this objective is being pursued in the area of insolvency procedures for non-
financial enterprises, for which continual efforts at harmonization are made. It should 
also be followed, a priori, in the banking industry, where it is essential not only to 
prevent the destruction of value but also to maintain public confidence in the banking 
system. In recent years, disorderly liquidations may have become more common due 
to a number of causes. Banks are reducing their branch network as a result of 
technological advancement and shifting consumer preferences; a fundamental 
consequence of this phenomenon is a diminished appetite for purchasing failing 
institutions. The economic crisis is also causing "overcapacity" in the EU banking 
industry, which struggles to remunerate capital on average, further lowering merger 
and acquisition returns. In these circumstances, the "franchise value" of failing banks 
is low, and potential buyers are frequently only willing to transact at negative prices. It 
is common knowledge, piecemeal liquidation would immediately undermine the 
bank's basic operations. Assets would have to be liquidated quickly at fire sale prices
and collateral would have to be enforced; non-insured liability holders would have to 
endure lengthy delays to receive only partial reimbursement; and borrowers, 
particularly small businesses, would be exposed to liquidity constraints, which could 
then lead to solvency issues. Other banks' confidence could be undermined, 
heightening the hazards for the economy as a whole. Consequently, disorderly 
piecemeal liquidation is largely untested at this time (Visco, 2021). 


63 
4.3. Developments in Greece 
In the first half of 2022, the stock of nonperforming loans (NPLs) in the 
banking sector continued to decline. The stock decreased by 20% from the end of 
2021 and stood at EUR 14.8 billion as of June 2022, showing a 10% non-performing 
loan ratio compared to 12.8% at the end of 2021. This decline was caused by loan 
write-offs, the accounting reclassification of the remaining Hercules securitizations, 
and certain outright sale transactions. By the end of 2024, the systemic banks hope 
to be closer to the average of their EU peers. Given the expiration of the Hercules 
Asset Protection Scheme in October 2022, systemic banks will need to rely 
increasingly on their in-house management of loans in default or at risk of default, as 
well as their capacity to offer viable long-term solutions or proceed with effective 
collateral recovery, to achieve this objective. This may prove to be more difficult than 
the inorganic NPL reduction strategy that has been the norm to until, especially for 
smaller institutions with large nonperforming loan percentages that have not utilized 
the Hercules plan (European Union, 2022). 
Image 11 Evolution of the stock of gross nonperforming loans and the corresponding non-performing 
loans ratio for Greek banks 
https://economy-finance.ec.europa.eu/system/files/2022-11/ip191_en.pdf
  
The net flow of new non-performing loans remains modest, but there are early 
indications of a rise in delinquencies as asset quality problems persist. Despite the 


64 
fact that pandemic-related state support measures (Gefyra I and II schemes) have 
nearly expired, default rates for these programs remain low (between 5 and 7 
percent). In the second quarter, there were no indications of a significant increase in 
the gross inflows of nonperforming loans into banks' loan portfolios. In addition, 
systemic banks continue to report lower-than-anticipated default rates for loans that 
have exited the Covid-19 payment moratorium, including instances in which 
Yüklə 0,77 Mb.

Dostları ilə paylaş:
1   ...   7   8   9   10   11   12   13   14   ...   18




Verilənlər bazası müəlliflik hüququ ilə müdafiə olunur ©azkurs.org 2024
rəhbərliyinə müraciət

gir | qeydiyyatdan keç
    Ana səhifə


yükləyin