basic human need:
the urge to speculate, or bet on short-term price movements.
One can use the futures market to mitigate risk—or one can use the futures
market to bet on the price of soybeans next year. One can use the bond market to
raise capital—or one can use it to bet on whether or not Ben Bernanke will cut
interest rates next month. One can use the stock market to invest in companies
and share their future profits—or one can buy a stock at 10:00 a.m. in hopes of
making a few bucks by noon. Financial products are to speculation what sporting
events are to gambling. They facilitate it, even if that is not their primary
purpose.
This is what went wrong with credit default swaps. The curious thing about
these contracts is that anyone can get into the action, regardless of whether or
not they are a party to the debt that is being guaranteed. Let’s
stick with the
example of your loser brother-in-law. It makes sense for you to use a credit
default swap to protect yourself against loss. However, that same market also
allows the rest of us to bet on whether or not your brother-in-law will pay back
the loan. That’s not hedging a bet; that’s speculation. So for any single debt,
there may be hundreds or thousands of contracts tied to whether or not it gets
repaid. Think about what that means if your brother-in-law starts skipping his
anger management classes and defaults. At that point, a $25,000 loss gets
magnified thousands of times over.
If the parties guaranteeing that debt haven’t done their homework (so they
don’t truly understand what a loser your brother-in-law is), or if they don’t care
(because they earn big bonuses for making dubious bets with the firm’s capital),
then an otherwise small set of economic setbacks can explode into something
bigger. That’s what happened when the American economy hit a real-estate-
related speed bump in 2007. AIG was the firm at the
heart of the credit default
debacle because it guaranteed a lot of debt that went bad. In his excellent 2009
assessment of the financial crisis, former chief economist for the International
Monetary Fund Simon Johnson writes:
Regulators, legislators, and academics almost all assumed that the
managers of these banks knew what they were doing. In retrospect,
they didn’t. AIG’s Financial Products division, for instance, made $2.5
million in pretax profits in 2005, largely by selling underpriced
insurance on complex, poorly understood securities. Often described
as “picking up nickels in front of a steamroller,”
this strategy is
profitable in ordinary years, and catastrophic in bad ones. As of last
fall, AIG had outstanding insurance on more than $400 billion in
securities. To date, the U.S. government, in an effort to rescue the
company, has committed to about $180 billion in investments and
loans to cover losses that AIG’s sophisticated risk modeling had said
were virtually impossible.
6
Raising capital. Protecting capital. Hedging risk. Speculating. That’s it. All the
frantic activity on Wall Street or LaSalle Street (home of the futures exchanges
in Chicago) fits into one or more of those buckets. The world of high finance is
often described as a rich man’s version of Las Vegas—risk, glamour, interesting
personalities, and lots of money changing hands.
Yet the analogy is terribly
inappropriate. Everything that happens in Las Vegas is a zero-sum game. If the
house wins a hand of blackjack, you lose. And the odds are stacked heavily in
favor of the house. If you play blackjack long enough—at least without counting
cards—it is a mathematical certainty that you will go broke. Las Vegas provides
entertainment, but it does not serve any broader social purpose. Wall Street does.
Most of what happens is a positive-sum game. Things get built; companies are
launched; individuals and companies manage risk that might otherwise be
devastating.
Not every transaction is a winner, of course. Just as individuals make
investments they later regret, the capital markets
are perfectly capable of
squandering huge amounts of capital; choose your favorite failed dot-com and
think of that as an example. Billions of dollars of capital flowed into businesses
that didn’t work. The real estate bubble and the Wall Street meltdown did the
same on an even bigger scale. Adam Smith’s invisible hand has hurled a lot of
capital into the ocean, never to be seen again. Meanwhile, some potentially
profitable enterprises are starved for capital because they have insufficient
collateral. Economists worry, for example, that too little
credit is available for
poor families who would like to invest in human capital. A college degree is an
excellent investment, but it is not something that can be repossessed in the event
of default.
Still, the financial markets do for capital what other markets do for everything
else: allocate it in a highly productive, albeit imperfect, way. Capital flows to
where it can earn the highest return, which is not a bad place to have it flowing
(as opposed to, say, into businesses run by top communist officials or friends of
the king). As
with the rest of the economy, government can be enemy or friend.
Government can mess up the capital markets in the same ways it can mess up
anything else—with overly burdensome taxes and regulations, by diverting
capital into pet projects, by refusing to allow creative destruction to work its
harshly efficient ways. Or government can make the financial markets work
better: by minimizing fraud, forcing transparency on the system, creating and
enforcing a regulatory framework, providing public goods that lower the cost of
doing
business, and so on. Once again, the wisdom lies in telling the difference.
Obviously the current crisis has presented some teachable moments. The
financial regulatory system needs to be patched up, if not completely
overhauled. The challenge will be to protect what a modern financial system
does best—allocating capital to productive investments and protecting us from
risks we can’t afford—while curtailing the excesses—stupid bets that enrich the
folks making them before eventually leaving a mess for the rest of us to clean
up.
All that is well and good.
But how does one get rich in the markets? One of my
former colleagues at
The Economist suggested that this book should be called
Dostları ilə paylaş: