Naked Economics: Undressing the Dismal Science pdfdrive com



Yüklə 1,42 Mb.
Pdf görüntüsü
səhifə121/122
tarix16.03.2023
ölçüsü1,42 Mb.
#88090
1   ...   114   115   116   117   118   119   120   121   122
Naked Economics Undressing the Dismal Science ( PDFDrive )

EPILOGUE. LIFE IN 2050
1.
“Out of Sight, Out of Mind,” The Economist, May 18, 2001.
2.
Denise Grady, “In Quest to Cure Rare Diseases, Some Get Left
Out,” New York Times, November 16, 1999.
3.
Anthony Lewis, “A Civilized Society,” New York Times, September
8, 2001.
4.
Phred Dvorak, “A Puzzle for Japan: Rock-Bottom Rates, but Few
Borrowers,” Wall Street Journal, October 25, 2001.
5.
Simon Johnson, “The Quiet Coup,” The Atlantic, May 2009.


*
When our Ford Explorer rolled over at 65 mph on an interstate three years later, we bought a Volvo.


*
I cannot fully explain why the pharmaceutical companies were so resistant to providing low-cost
HIV/AIDS drugs to Africa. These countries will never be able to pay the high prices charged in the
developed world, so the companies would not be forgoing profits by selling the drugs cheaply. In places
like South Africa, it’s either cheap drugs or no drugs. This would appear to be a perfect opportunity for
price discrimination: Make the drugs cheap in Cape Town and expensive in New York. True, price
discrimination could create an opportunity for a black market; drugs sold cheaply in Africa could be resold
illegally at high prices in New York. But that seems a manageable problem relative to the huge public
relations cost of denying important drugs to large swathes of the world’s population.


*
There is a subtle but important analytical point here. Those who argue that tax cuts increase government
revenues often point out, correctly, that government revenues are higher after a major tax cut than before.
But this is not the appropriate comparison to make. The question we should ask is whether government
revenues after the tax cut are higher than they would have been if there had not been a tax cut. The reason
this distinction matters is that inflation and economic growth push government revenues higher year after
year even when the tax rate is unchanged. So it’s entirely plausible that revenues would have climbed 5
percent without the tax cut; if they climb 2 percent with the tax cut, government revenues are indeed higher
than the year before—but lower than they would have been without the tax cut. If spending growth is not
curtailed to match this new revenue reality, then budget deficits will result, which is usually what happens.


*
Your actual return would be much higher, since much of the purchase would be financed. If you put
$50,000 down, for example, you would have earned $250,000 on a $50,000 investment (minus the interest
you paid to carry the mortgage during the period you owned the house).


*
The expected return is 0.5($400,000) + 0.5($0) = $200,000, which is a 100 percent return on your
$100,000 investment.



This exercise is somewhat oversimplified. The flips of a coin are independent, while the performance of
individual stocks are not. Some events, such as an interest rate hike, will affect the whole market. Thus,
buying two stocks will not offer as much diversification as would splitting your portfolio between two flips
of a coin. Nonetheless, the broader point is valid.


*
To derive the Gini index, the personal incomes in a country are arranged in ascending order. A line, the
Lorenz curve, plots the cumulative share of personal income against the cumulative share of population.
Total equality would be a 45-degree line. The Gini coefficient is the ratio of the area between the diagonal
and the Lorenz curve to the total area under the diagonal.


*
I can’t remember the exact numbers, but they were something along these lines.


*
Okay, that’s not exactly true. At the height of the financial crisis, right around the time that Lehman
Brothers declared bankruptcy, the yield on three-month U.S. Treasury notes fell below zero, which means
that the nominal interest rate had turned negative. Remarkably, investors were paying more for something
than it promised to pay them back in three months. For policymakers, this was a sign of panic. Keith
Hennessey, director of the National Economic Council in the White House, told James Stewart of The New
Yorker, “Treasury rates went negative! People were locking in a loss just to protect their money.”


*
Soros borrowed a huge sum in British pounds and immediately traded them for stronger currencies, such
as the German deutsche mark. When the Brits eventually dropped out of the ERM and devalued the pound,
he swapped his currency holdings back for more pounds than he had originally borrowed. He paid back his
loans and kept the difference. Numbers make this all more intuitive. Suppose Soros borrowed 10 billion
pounds and swapped them immediately for 10 billion deutsche marks. (The exchange rates and amounts are
contrived to make the numbers easier.) When the pound was devalued, its value fell by more than 10
percent, so that 10 billion deutsche marks subsequently bought 11 billion pounds. Soros swapped his 10
billion deutsche marks for 11 billion pounds. He paid back his 10-billion-pound loan and kept the tidy
balance for himself (or, more accurately, for his investment funds). Soros supplemented his currency gains
with ancillary bets related to how the devaluation would affect European stocks and bonds.


*
Economists make a distinction between the nominal exchange rate, which is the official rate at which one
currency can be exchanged for another (the numbers posted on the board at the currency exchange), and the
real exchange rate, which takes inflation into account in both countries and is therefore a better indicator of
changes in purchasing power of one currency relative to another. For example, assume that the U.S. dollar
can be exchanged at your local bank for 10 pesos. Further assume that (1) inflation is zero in the United
States and 10 percent annually in Mexico; and (2) a year later your local bank will exchange $1 for 11
pesos. In nominal terms, the U.S. dollar has appreciated 10 percent relative to the peso (each dollar buys 10
percent more pesos). But the real exchange rate hasn’t changed at all. You will get 10 percent more pesos at
the currency exchange window than you did last year, but because of inflation over the course of the year,
each peso now buys 10 percent less than it used to. As a result, the total purchasing power of the pesos that
you get from the bank teller this year for your $100 is exactly the same as the purchasing power of the
(fewer) pesos you got for your $100 last year. Any reference to exchange rates in the balance of this chapter
refers to real exchange rates.



Yüklə 1,42 Mb.

Dostları ilə paylaş:
1   ...   114   115   116   117   118   119   120   121   122




Verilənlər bazası müəlliflik hüququ ilə müdafiə olunur ©azkurs.org 2024
rəhbərliyinə müraciət

gir | qeydiyyatdan keç
    Ana səhifə


yükləyin