Naked Economics: Undressing the Dismal Science pdfdrive com



Yüklə 1,42 Mb.
Pdf görüntüsü
səhifə81/122
tarix16.03.2023
ölçüsü1,42 Mb.
#88090
1   ...   77   78   79   80   81   82   83   84   ...   122
Naked Economics Undressing the Dismal Science ( PDFDrive )

CHAPTER
12


Trade and Globalization:
The good news about Asian sweatshops
I
magine a spectacular invention: a machine that can convert corn into stereo
equipment. When running at full capacity, this machine can turn fifty bushels of
corn into a DVD player. Or with one switch of the dial, it will convert fifteen
hundred bushels of soybeans into a four-door sedan. But this machine is even
more versatile than that; when properly programmed, it can turn Windows
software into the finest French wines. Or a Boeing 777 into enough fresh fruits
and vegetables to feed a city for months. Indeed, the most amazing thing about
this invention is that it can be set up anywhere in the world and programmed to
turn whatever is grown or produced there into things that are usually much
harder to come by.
Remarkably, it works for poor countries, too. Developing nations can put the
things they manage to produce—commodities, cheap textiles, basic
manufactured goods—into the machine and obtain goods that might otherwise
be denied them: food, medicine, more advanced manufactured goods.
Obviously, poor countries that have access to this machine would grow faster
than countries that did not. We would expect that making this machine
accessible to poor countries would be part of our strategy for lifting billions of
people around the globe out of dire poverty.
Amazingly, this invention already exists. It is called trade.
If I write books for a living and use my income to buy a car made in Detroit,
there is nothing particularly controversial about the transaction. It makes me
better off, and it makes the car company better off, too. That’s Chapter 1 kind of
stuff. A modern economy is built on trade. We pay others to do or make things
that we can’t—everything from manufacturing a car to removing an appendix.
As significant, we pay people to do all kinds of things that we could do but
choose not to, usually because we have something better to do with our time. We
pay others to brew coffee, make sandwiches, change the oil, clean the house,
even walk the dog. Starbucks was not built on any great technological
breakthrough. The company simply recognized that busy people will regularly
pay several dollars for a cup of coffee rather than make their own or drink the
lousy stuff that has been sitting around the office for six hours.
The easiest way to appreciate the gains from trade is to imagine life without it.
You would wake up early in a small, drafty house that you had built yourself.
You would put on clothes that you wove yourself after shearing the two sheep


that graze in your backyard. Then you would pluck a few coffee beans off the
scraggly tree that does not grow particularly well in Minneapolis—all the while
hoping that your chicken had laid an egg overnight so that you might have
something to eat for breakfast. The bottom line is that our standard of living is
high because we are able to focus on the tasks that we do best and trade for
everything else.
Why would these kinds of transactions be different if a product or service
originated in Germany or India? They’re not, really. We’ve crossed a political
boundary, but the economics have not changed in any significant way.
Individuals and firms do business with one another because it makes them both
better off. That is true for a worker at a Nike factory in Vietnam, an autoworker
in Detroit, a Frenchman eating a McDonald’s hamburger in Bordeaux, or an
American drinking a fine Burgundy in Chicago. Any rational discussion of trade
must begin with the idea that people in Chad or Togo or South Korea are no
different from you or me; they do things that they hope will make their lives
better. Trade is one of those things. Paul Krugman has noted, “You could say—
and I would—that globalization, driven not by human goodness but by the profit
motive, has done far more good for far more people than all the foreign aid and
soft loans ever provided by well-intentioned governments and international
agencies.” Then he adds wistfully, “But in saying this, I know from experience
that I have guaranteed myself a barrage of hate mail.”
1
Such is the nature of “globalization,” the term that has come to represent the
increase in the international flow of goods and services. Americans and most
others on the planet are more likely than ever to buy goods or services from
another nation and to sell goods and services abroad in return. In the late 1980s,
I was traveling through Asia while writing a series of articles for a daily
newspaper in New Hampshire. In a relatively remote part of Bali, I was so
surprised to find a Kentucky Fried Chicken that I wrote a story about it.
“Colonel Sanders has succeeded in putting fast-food restaurants in the most
remote areas of the world,” I wrote. Had I realized that the idea of “cultural
homogenization” would become a flashpoint for civil unrest a decade later, I
might have become rich and famous as one of the earliest commentators on
globalization. Instead, I merely noted, “In this relatively undisturbed
environment, Kentucky Fried Chicken seems out of place.”
2
That KFC restaurant was more than the curiosity that I made it out to be. It
was a tangible sign of what the statistics clearly show: The world is growing


more economically interdependent. The world’s exports as a share of global
GDP have climbed from 8 percent in 1950 to around 25 percent today.
3
U.S.
exports as a fraction of GDP grew from 5 percent to nearly 10 percent over the
same stretch. It is worth noting that the bulk of the American economy still
consists of goods and services produced for domestic consumption. At the same
time, because of the sheer size of that economy, America is one of the world’s
largest exporters, behind only China and Germany in total value. The United
States has much to gain from an open, international trading system. Then again,
so does the rest of the world.
Having made that case in many different venues, now I get hate mail, too.
Sometimes it’s actually kind of clever. My favorite is an e-mail that came in
response to a column arguing that a richer, rapidly growing India is good for the
United States. After the usual introduction arguing that my job should be
outsourced to some low wage country as soon as possible, the e-mail concluded,
“Why don’t you and Tom Friedman [author of the pro-globalization book The
World Is Flat] get a room together? The world isn’t flat, it’s just your head!”
Others tend to be less subtle, such as the e-mail with the subject line: YOU
SUCK!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!! (Yes, that is the exact number of exclamation points.)
All those exclamation points notwithstanding, nearly all theory and evidence
suggest that the benefits of international trade far exceed the costs. The topic is
worthy of an entire book; some good ones wade into everything from the
administrative structure of the WTO to the fate of sea turtles caught in shrimp
nets. Yet the basic ideas underlying the costs and benefits of globalization are
simple and straightforward. Indeed, no modern issue has elicited so much sloppy
thinking. The case for international trade is built on the most basic ideas in
economics.

Yüklə 1,42 Mb.

Dostları ilə paylaş:
1   ...   77   78   79   80   81   82   83   84   ...   122




Verilənlər bazası müəlliflik hüququ ilə müdafiə olunur ©azkurs.org 2024
rəhbərliyinə müraciət

gir | qeydiyyatdan keç
    Ana səhifə


yükləyin