1
Introduction
The recent proliferation of regional trading blocs is striking with the signing of
numerous new and overhauled preferential trade agreements (PTAs) since 1990.
1
There remains however, an ongoing debate between economists and politicians as to
whether regional trade agreements (RTAs) represent “building” or “stumbling” blocks
(Bhagwati 1991). The welcome for the opportunities this new wave of regionalism
is supposed to bring is not therefore, all encompassing with some fearing that regional
economic integration corrupts and undermines progress towards global free trade
expounded by the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) and more recently
the World Trade Organisation (WTO). Others however, are more positive (see e.g.
Summers 1991, Lawrence 1991, Ethier 1998, IDS 1999 and the World Bank 1999)
and see any trade liberalisation as good whatever its source and PTA’s as a second
best means of achieving trade liberalisation when multilateral negotiations stall.
2
Closer European integration and a number of regional initiatives from the United
States transformed the global economic climate in the late 1980’s and meant that it
was increasingly important for smaller developing and newly industrialised countries
to generate closer regional economic ties. One of the more influential regional
1
A PTA is an agreement between two countries where the tariff imposed between them is
lower than that on goods from countries outside the agreement. PTAs include regional
trade agreements between countries within a given geographical area and free trade
agreements that have no tariffs between member countries but individual tariff structures
with non-members.
2
In addition to existing agreements such as the European Union (EU) and the European
Free Trade Association (EFTA) other new or rejuvenated regional trade agreements
include the Common Market of the South (MERCOSUR, 1991), the North American Free
Trade Association (NAFTA, 1994), the ADEAN Pact (ANDEAN), and the Central
American Common Market (CACM) in the Americas. In Africa the 1990’s saw the
creation of the Union Duaniere et Economique de l’Afrique Central (UDEAC), the
Common Market for Eastern and Southern African States (COMESA) and the Union
Economique et Monetaire Quest-Africaine (UEMOA). According to the WTO (2001) all
WTO members have taken part in at least one episode of regional integration.
4
developments was in the Southeast Asian region where me mbers of the Association of
Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) agreed in 1992 to establish the ASEAN Free Trade
Area (AFTA) that currently has a membership of ten countries and a population of
over 500 million. Moreover, the recent emergence of China as an economic power
in the region following its membership of the WTO has led to a renewed vigour
among ASEAN nations to pursue the goal of regional cooperation.
Broadly speaking, the last thirty years has seen a robust economic performance from
ASEAN countries. One reason for this apparent success was that the engine of
growth was primarily extra-regional rather than intra-regional trade and questions
therefore, the need for a Southeast Asian regional grouping. Krugman (1991)
introduced the notion of a “natural trading block” based on geographical proximity
that could be both efficient and welfare increasing. He also noted however, that an
RTA based on being a member of a political club could induce regional bias to trade
patterns that can be welfare reducing if trade diversion is greater than trade creation.
This raises the question of whether AFTA has any real economic rationality over its
mere political and symbolic meaning.
The primary objective of this paper therefore, is to investigate the effect of AF TA and
the “anticipation” effect of AFTA on intra- and extra-regional trade flows by a
comparison of trade patterns before and after the start of the AFTA process. Given
the “openness” of ASEAN countries it is important to consider not only intra-ASEAN
trade but also the effect of AFTA on non-members trade. By doing so we hope to be
able to reveal whether AFTA; (i) increases trade among members (ii) harms
5
non- member countries and (iii) contributes to or undermines future liberalisation
negotiations.
Any post-1992 AFTA analysis is however, further complicated by the ramifications of
the Asian economic crisis that began with a massive speculative attack on the Thai
baht May 14-15, 1997. The years following the crisis saw ASEAN members suffer
significant structural and financial difficulties (including reduced aggregate growth
and job losses) associated with large currency depreciations and capital outflows.
Relatively few studies examine the period during and after the Asian crisis even
though the affects on the economies of the region were often profound (Clarete et al.
2002 is one exception). For example, according to World Bank data, Indonesia
moved from a GDP growth rate of 4.9% in 1997 and a financial account surplus of
10.8 (US$ billion) in 1996 to a GDP growth rate of -13.7% and a financial account
deficit of –10.3 (US$ billion) in 1998. Likewise, Thailand moved from a positive
growth rate of 5.5% in 1996 to –10.2% in 1998 and a change from a financial account
surplus of 19.5 (US$ billion) in 1996 to deficits of –16.9 and –14.6 (US$ billions) in
1998 and 1999 respectively.
In this paper we are interested in whether ASEAN countries attempted to solve their
problems with the help of newly strengthened intra-ASEAN relations and whether the
result of the crisis was to significantly change the structure of imports and exports and
result in the collapse of long-standing trade relationships. As a consequence, we
address whether the aims of AFTA to increase intra-regional trade and cooperation
were helped or hindered by the Asian crisis.
6
The existing empirical literature suggests two main approaches for measuring the
economic impact of PTAs. Partial or general equilibrium models provide an ex ante
approach that includes computable general equilibrium models to empirically predict
the impact of AFTA on the economy and constituent trade flows (see e.g. Imada et al.
1991, Adams and Park 1995 and DeRosa 1995). The second approach focuses on ex
post investigations of bilateral trade values using the so-called gravity equation.
Simple examples of the application of a gravity type approach to intra-regional trade
bias of selected regional groupings (one being ASEAN) include Hamilton and
Winters (1992), Frankel (1993) and Sharma and Chua (2000) while Elbadawi (1997),
Frankel and Wei (1998), Endoh (1999, 2000) and Soloaga and Winters (2001) present
useful extensions of the basic model.
The core methodology in this paper is based upon Endoh (2000) and Soloaga and
Winters (2001) but the analysis concentrates on ASEAN intra- and extra-regional bias
in bilateral trade flows and how these trade relationships have altered over time
paying particular attention to the periods before and after the signing of AFTA as well
as the crucial years prior to and following the Asian crisis.
The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 provides some historical background to
regional cooperation in the Southeast Asian region. Section 3 describes the
methodology and estimates a modified gravity equation while Section 4 discusses the
results and Section 5 concludes.
|