Productivity is the concept that takes the suck out of Ross Perot’s “giant
sucking sound.” When Ross Perot ran for president in 1992 as an independent,
one of his defining positions was opposition to the North American Free Tree
Agreement (NAFTA). Perot reasoned that if we opened our borders to free trade
with Mexico, then millions of jobs would flee south of the border. Why wouldn’t
a firm relocate to Mexico when the average Mexican factory worker earns a
fraction of the wages paid to American workers? The answer is productivity.
Can American workers compete against foreign workers who earn half as much
or less?
Yes, most of us can. We produce more than Mexican workers—much
more in many cases—because we are better-educated, because we are healthier,
because we have better access to capital and technology, and because we have
more efficient government institutions and better public infrastructure. Can a
Vietnamese peasant with two years of education do your job? Probably not.
Of course, there are industries in which American
workers are not productive
enough to justify their relatively high wages, such as manufacturing textiles and
shoes. These are industries that require relatively unskilled labor, which is more
expensive in this country than in the developing world. Can a Vietnamese
peasant sew basketball shoes together? Yes—and for a lot less than the
American minimum wage. American firms will look to “outsource” jobs to other
countries only if the wages in those countries are cheap relative to what those
workers can produce. A worker who costs a tenth as much and produces a tenth
as much is no great bargain. A worker who costs a tenth as much and produces
half as much probably is.
While Ross Perot was warning that most of the U.S.
economy would migrate
to Guadalajara, mainstream economists predicted that NAFTA would have a
modest but positive effect on American employment. Some jobs would be lost to
Mexican competition; more jobs would be created as exports to Mexico
increased. We are now more than a decade into NAFTA, and that is exactly what
happened. Economists reckon that the effect on overall employment was
positive, albeit very small relative to the size of the U.S. economy.
Will our children be better off than we are? Yes, if they are more productive
than we are, which has been the pattern throughout American history.
Productivity
growth is what improves our standard of living. If productivity
grows at 2
percent a year, then we will become 2 percent richer every year.
Why? Because we can take the same inputs and make 2 percent more stuff. (Or
we could make the same amount of stuff with 2 percent fewer inputs.) One of the
most interesting debates in economics is whether or not the American economy
has undergone a sharp increase in the rate of productivity growth. Some
economists, including Alan Greenspan during his tenure as Fed chairman, have
argued that investments in information technology have led to permanently
higher rates of productivity growth. Others, such as Robert Gordon at
Northwestern University, believe that productivity growth has not changed
significantly when one interprets the data properly.
The answer to that debate matters enormously. From 1947 to 1975,
productivity grew at an annual rate of 2.7 percent a year. From 1975 until the
mid-1990s, for reasons that are still not fully understood, productivity growth
slowed to 1.4 percent a year. Then it got better again; from 2000 to 2008,
productivity growth returned to a much healthier 2.5 percent annually. That may
seem
like a trivial difference; in fact, it has a profound effect on our standard of
living. One handy trick in finance and economics is the rule of 72; divide 72 by a
rate of growth (or a rate of interest) and the answer will tell you roughly how
long it will take for a growing quantity to double (e.g., the principal in a bank
account paying 4 percent interest will double in roughly 18 years). When
productivity grows at 2.7 percent a year, our standard of living doubles every
twenty-seven years. At 1.4 percent, it doubles every fifty-one years.
Productivity growth makes us richer, regardless of what is going on in the rest
of the world. If productivity grows at 4 percent in Japan and 2 percent in the
United States,
then both countries are getting richer. To understand why, go
back to our simple farm economy. If one farmer is raising 2 percent more corn
and hogs every year and his neighbor is raising 4
percent more, then they are
eating more every year (or trading more away). If this disparity goes on for a
long time, one of them will become significantly richer than the other, which
may become a source of envy or political friction, but they are both growing
steadily better off. The important point is that productivity growth, like so much
else in economics, is not a zero-sum game.
What would be the effect on America if 500 million people in India became
more productive and gradually moved from poverty to the middle class? We
would become richer, too. Poor villagers currently subsisting on $1
a day cannot
afford to buy our software, our cars, our music, our books, our agricultural
exports. If they were wealthier, they could. Meanwhile, some of those 500
million people, whose potential is currently wasted for lack of education, would
produce goods and services that are superior to what we have now, making us
better off. One of those newly educated peasants
might be the person who
discovers an AIDS vaccine or a process for reversing global warming. To
paraphrase the United Negro College Fund, 500 million minds are a terrible
thing to waste.
Productivity growth depends on investment—in physical capital, in human
capital, in research and development, and even in things like more effective
government institutions. These investments require that we give up consumption
in the present in order to be able to consume more in the future. If you skip
buying a BMW and invest in a college education instead, your future income
will be higher.
Similarly, a software company may forgo paying its shareholders
a dividend and plow its profits back into the development of a new, better
product. The government may collect taxes (depriving us of some current
consumption) to fund research in genetics that improves our health in the future.
In each case, we spend resources now so that we will become more productive
later. When we turn to the macroeconomy—our study of the economy as a
whole—one important concern will be whether or not we are investing enough
as a nation to continue growing our standard of living.
Our legal, regulatory, and tax structures also affect productivity growth. High
taxes, bad government,
poorly defined property rights, or excessive regulation
can diminish or eliminate the incentive to make productive investments.
Collective farms, for example, are a very bad way to organize agriculture. Social
factors, such as discrimination, can profoundly affect productivity. A society that
does not educate its women or that denies opportunities to members of a
Dostları ilə paylaş: