ISSN 0143-6597 print/ISSN 1360-2241 online/03/020235-19
᭧ 2003 Third World Quarterly
DOI: 10.1080/0143659032000074574
235
Third World Quarterly, Vol 24, No 2, pp 235–253, 2003
Southeast Asian economic regionalism during the 1990s took the form of a
regional free trade area, namely the
ASEAN
Free Trade Area (
AFTA
), which was
jointly initiated in 1992 by Brunei, Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines,
Singapore and Thailand.
1
AFTA
has conventionally been explained as a project of
open regionalism, adopted by the
ASEAN
member governments as an instrument
to attract foreign direct investment (
FDI
) to the
ASEAN
region through the ‘carrot’
of the single regional market. Yet, when the same governments formally incorpo-
rated an investment liberalisation component programme within the
AFTA
project
in 1998, they opted to accord full national treatment and market access privileges
to foreign (non-
ASEAN
) investors at least 10 years later than to domestic or
ASEAN
Attempting developmental
regionalism through
AFTA
: the
domestic sources of regional
governance
HELEN E S NESADURAI
A
BSTRACT
The
ASEAN
Free Trade Area (
AFTA
) has conventionally been explained
as a project of open regionalism adopted by the
ASEAN
member governments to
attract foreign direct investment to the region through the ‘carrot’ of the single
regional market. Yet, when the same governments incorporated an investment
liberalisation component programme within the
AFTA
project in 1998, they opted
to accord full national treatment and market access privileges to foreign (non-
ASEAN
) investors at least 10 years later than to domestic or
ASEAN
national
investors. Although member governments removed this particular discriminatory
clause in September 2001, the fact that a distinction between foreign and
domestic investors was adopted and maintained for a three-year period is
puzzling given
AFTA
’s acknowledged role as a magnet for foreign investment.
Although
AFTA
is clearly a response to the pressures of globalisation, the
available theoretical models of the relationship between globalisation and
regionalism are unable to account for this empirical anomaly because they do
not make a distinction between foreign-owned and domestic-owned capital.
This paper advances the notion of ‘developmental regionalism’ as a way to
incorporate domestic-owned capital in analysing the globalisation–regionalism
relationship, which allows for a more robust explanation of the empirical puzzle
outlined above.
Helen E S Nesadurai is at the Institute of Defence and Strategic Studies of Nanyang Technological
University, Singapore. E-mail: isesnesadurai@ntu.edu.sg.
HELEN E S NESADURAI
national investors. Although member governments removed this particular
discriminatory clause in September 2001, the fact that a distinction between
foreign and domestic investors was adopted and maintained for a three-year
period is puzzling given
AFTA
’s acknowledged role as a magnet for foreign
investment.
This article explains this development as a move by
ASEAN
member govern-
ments, spearheaded by Malaysia, to use the investment liberalisation programme
of
AFTA
as a developmental tool to build up domestic firms, in addition to using
AFTA
’s tariff liberalisation programme to attract
FDI
to the single regional market.
Specifically, the idea was to nurture domestic capital by using both the expanded
regional market and the offer of temporary investment privileges to domestic-
owned capital ahead of foreign investors. These temporary investment privileges
took the form of earlier market access and national treatment for
ASEAN
national
investors in the
ASEAN
regional market, particularly in non-manufacturing
sectors, and represents an attempt at what I term ‘developmental’ regionalism.
AFTA
, in short, displayed the features of both open and developmental regional-
ism, thanks to the political significance of foreign and domestic-owned capital in
ASEAN
. While both forms of regionalism were driven by the imperative of
growth, distributive concerns were woven into the concern with growth in
developmental regionalism as governments sought to direct economic benefits to
those segments of domestic capital that were important in sustaining elite rule.
The analysis suggests that, although
AFTA
was triggered in the first instance by
the external pressures associated with globalisation, it was the tussle at the
domestic level between the imperatives of growth and domestic distribution
(directed towards politically important domestic-owned businesses) that shaped
the distinctive way economic co-operation unfolded. In short, the nature of
domestic coalitions was a crucial mediating variable between globalisation and
regional outcomes.
Following this brief introduction, the next section develops the notion of
developmental regionalism by drawing on strategic trade theory from inter-
national economics. This section also elaborates on how developmental region-
alism relates to globalisation and suggests why such a project might have proved
attractive to governments in
ASEAN
. The third and fourth sections apply this
concept to
AFTA
, explaining developmental regionalism as a project through
which a number of
ASEAN
governments sought to nurture domestic capital amid
global market competition,
2
while the fifth section reveals why member govern-
ments were prompted to halt their attempt at developmental regionalism in
September 2001.
Conceptualising developmental regionalism
Contemporary regionalism is generally conceived of as a response to the
pressures and incentives associated with economic globalisation (Gamble &
Payne, 1998; Hveem, 2000; Mittelman, 2000: 111). One source of these pressures
and incentives is the growing economic inter-linkages between countries that
generate common interests in co-operation (Hurrell, 1995: 56). But globalisation
is much more than the interactions and interdependences between countries.
236
ATTEMPTING DEVELOPMENTAL REGIONALISM THROUGH AFTA
Globalisation is best regarded as a multi-faceted structural phenomenon
generating multiple pressures and incentives arising from the complex interplay
of its material, institutional and cognitive dimensions (Higgott, 2000: 70).
Material changes in production, trade and finance, especially since the 1980s
have heightened both the pressures on governments as well as competition
among them as they seek to generate wealth for their societies by attracting
transnational corporations (
TNC
s) to locate within their territories (Stopford &
Strange, 1991: 1). Increasingly, the assets required for wealth creation in the
‘new’ world economy centre on information, technological innovation as well as
management and organisational competence, what are termed ‘created assets’
that reside within these global firms (Dunning, 1993: 6). While previously salient
‘natural assets’ such as labour, land and natural resources remain important in
many sectors, governments wishing to involve their economies in higher value-
added economic activities have become increasingly reliant on the wealth-
creating resources controlled by
TNC
s (Stopford & Strange, 1991: 1). In addition,
neoliberal economic rules instituted at the multilateral level, especially through
the World Trade Organization (
WTO
), increasingly prescribe free markets and
proscribe government intervention in and control of economic activity, which
effectively adds a second set of pressures on governments unable to employ
traditional policy instruments to meet domestic social and political objectives
(George, 2001).
Moreover, these multilateral rules are creating an environment in which
TNC
s
face fewer and fewer restrictions worldwide on their activities. This has
contributed to a shared consciousness among governments of heightened global
market competition vis-à-vis the global corporate giants and a sense of the
growing dominance of these
TNC
s in markets everywhere. Governments, there-
fore, are not only reacting to actual external pressures associated with globalisa-
tion, they are increasingly responding in anticipatory fashion to perceived
challenges to the competitiveness of the home economy and of home country
firms (Palan & Abbott, 1996: 32). Regionalism can emerge as one such response
to these multiple pressures.
The literature identifies two ideal-type models of the globalisation–regionalism
relationship, with open regionalism the dominant theoretical model as well as in
practice (Mittelman, 2000: 126). Open regionalism is aimed primarily at
advancing the competitive position of business in global competition (the liberal
economic interpretation),
3
or to attract wealth-creating
FDI
to the region amid
competition with other sites for it (the economic realist interpretation).
4
The main
driving force behind open regionalism is the concern with economic efficiency
or, more broadly, with ensuring economic growth through participation in global-
wealth creating activities. An alternative ideal-type model of the globalisation–
regionalism relationship in the literature is the ‘resistance to globalisation’ model
of regionalism (Hveem, 2000: 75–78). Resistance projects are driven largely by
concern with non-economic or social values like distribution and social justice,
and by seeking to preserve through regionalism particular forms of domestic
social/economic arrangements that are arguably difficult to sustain individually
amid globalisation (Mittelman, 2000: 116–130). While proponents of regionalism
in this model seek to resist globalisation, the advocates of both variants of open
237
HELEN E S NESADURAI
regionalism accept full engagement with globalisation.
While providing useful insights into the relationship between globalisation and
regionalism, these two models are limited in their treatment of the state–market
relationship, particularly that between governments and fractions of capital
distinguished by their ownership—domestic or foreign.
5
Neither variant of open
regionalism makes adequate distinction between foreign and domestic capital,
although the former is privileged in the
FDI
variant. Although it may be increas-
ingly difficult to distinguish business in terms of its nationality—the ‘who is us?’
question posed by Robert Reich (1991: 304)—such a distinction nevertheless
remains relevant in particular political contexts where policy makers and
politicians do consciously make this distinction for various political reasons. In
these settings, and this is especially true for developing countries where domestic
capital is usually not as well developed as foreign capital but often plays a crucial
political role, governments may well respond to globalisation in ways that
attempt to preserve and nurture domestic capital.
By making an analytical distinction between foreign and domestic capital, a
third model of regionalism is possible—developmental regionalism (Nesadurai,
2001: 74–79). Deriving from the notion of the developmental state, develop-
mental regionalism encapsulates the developmental state idea of state inter-
vention in markets to promote national development agendas, in this case by
adopting an approach to regionalism through which to nurture emerging domestic
firms to eventually become internationally competitive. This is achieved through
two instruments: one, the expanded regional market generated through inter-state
co-operation; two, temporary protection or privileges for domestic capital in this
expanded market. According to strategic trade theory from the international
economics discipline, both measures can help to secure benefits for domestic
firms over their foreign competitors.
6
Proponents of developmental regionalism, it is argued, are not necessarily
resisting globalisation through regionalism. They do not fully accept the
anticipated dominance of foreign/global firms that is associated with globalisa-
tion, however, and attempt to support the development of domestic capital
through regionalism. While the concern here is with distribution—the selective
allocation of economic benefits including rents—to domestic businesses as a
means to preserve and nurture them, the growth/efficiency imperative is not
absent either. Rather, the growth imperative is infused with distributive concerns.
Developmental regionalism is, therefore, not about resisting globalisation
completely, but neither is it about complete acquiescence to global market forces.
Instead, it encompasses a period of temporary and limited resistance to aspects of
globalisation through which attempts are made to build capabilities that will
enable domestic businesses eventually to participate in global market activities.
This model of regionalism, therefore, allows us to consider departures from open
regionalism as representing a distinct approach to regionalism rather than merely
as inconsistencies in open regionalism or as instances of protectionism.
The question that remains, however, is why political actors would seek to
nurture domestic capital. The following discussion addresses this question with
regard to the specific case of
ASEAN
. The analysis is based on a general/basic
model of domestic politics that emphasises the preferences of key domestic groups
238
ATTEMPTING DEVELOPMENTAL REGIONALISM THROUGH AFTA
and the role of formal and informal domestic institutions and political practices in
shaping preference representation in policy making (Moravcsik, 1997).
Domestic coalitions and elite politics in
ASEAN
While political systems in
ASEAN
during much of the 1990s ranged from
democracies, to semi-democracies and authoritarian regimes, all the
ASEAN
countries shared the basic characteristics of elite governance political systems
where political power was largely in the hands of elites, despite the presence of
mechanisms for citizen participation (McCargo, 1998: 127). The political elite
was, however, not completely insulated from domestic society, and needed to
respond to concerns arising from this level in order to maintain its rule and its
legitimacy, which remained fragile throughout the 1990s. In such settings,
political elites depend on two factors to maintain themselves in power and ensure
the stability and security of the prevailing domestic regime or political system.
On the one hand, political elites need the support of citizens to maintain their
right to rule and to ensure political order, and this is largely achieved through
creating material wealth for citizens—the notion of performance legitimacy,
which remains relevant to date (Alagappa, 1995: 330; Stubbs, 2001). This
explains the preoccupation of political leaders with securing and maintaining key
sources of growth in the economy, of which
FDI
is pre-eminent in
ASEAN
. On the
other hand, elite rule is also sustained by unity and accommodation between
members of the elite/governing coalition (Haggard & Kaufman, 1997). Political
elites selectively distribute economic benefits to their elite partners as a primary
means to achieve elite unity.
By the 1990s it was the accommodation between the political elite and
an emerging domestic business class that was crucial in much of
ASEAN
. The
material and other forms of political support provided by domestic businesses
helped incumbent political elites maintain their power base, while the former in
turn received economic privileges through preferential policies instituted by the
latter. In addition, domestic businesses were privileged because they helped
political actors fulfil broader political aims. This was especially clear in the
Malaysian and Indonesian cases, where political legitimacy also rests on the
capacity of the state to develop, respectively, an ethnic Malay and an indigenous
Indonesian domestic capital class, particularly to offset the dominance of ethnic
Chinese capital.
7
Thus, although political actors were powerful and had some
degree of autonomy in decision making, they were, nevertheless, constrained by
the need to respond to domestic society at these two levels—citizens in general
and domestic business interests allied with political and state elites.
Tensions can emerge when particular policies generate significant trade-offs
between the growth and distributive imperatives,
8
or between maximising wealth
and efficiency in society as a whole and maximising the wealth of a segment of
society. In much of
ASEAN
, foreign capital remains a key source of growth and
exports, particularly in the high value-added and advanced sectors of the
economy that virtually all governments are increasingly targeting, although
domestic-owned firms are not entirely absent from this picture. On the other
hand, the distributive imperative in
ASEAN
, where it exists, is usually aimed at
239
HELEN E S NESADURAI
privileging domestic-owned capital or segments of it that are also close allies of
the political elite. A simplifying, though not unreasonable, assumption made in
the paper is that the foreign capital governments are targeting is internationally
orientated and thus in favour of liberal market policies that maximise growth.
While domestic capital may be either internationally orientated or
emerging/inward focused, it is when the political elite is closely allied to the
latter that the tension between growth and distribution becomes pronounced.
Since this segment of domestic capital is not as well developed as foreign capital,
policy makers may well adopt measures to protect, preserve and/or nurture
emerging domestic capital vis-à-vis foreign capital if the former is to survive
direct competition with the latter.
When distributive policies involve restricting the domestic operations of
foreign (or internationally orientated) firms, growth prospects may be weakened
if the latter are significant agents of growth. Growth need not, however, be
disrupted if the extent of distribution is limited, either to particular sectors or in
terms of time. On the other hand, governments may find it necessary to limit their
distributive agenda during times of economic distress, or expected economic
hardship, which will affect citizens in general through unemployment, for
instance, as well as threaten elite unity (Haggard & Kaufman, 1997). By
threatening the political future of incumbent political elites, economic decline, or
the prospect of it, often compels governments to restore the conditions favouring
growth, particularly since growth will allow distribution to take place with fewer
costs than under conditions of generalised economic decline. The rest of this
paper employs the analytical framework described above to account for develop-
ments in
AFTA
.
AFTA
: encompassing open and developmental regionalism
AFTA
has generally been explained as a project of open regionalism aimed at
attracting
FDI
to member economies through the carrot of the single regional
market.
9
Globalisation had by the early 1990s significantly altered patterns and
flows of
FDI
and increased worldwide competition for it. By 1991–92, the surge
of
FDI
into
ASEAN
, particularly from its traditional sources in the
OECD
countries,
Taiwan and Hong Kong had moderated, flowing instead to China (Hay, 1996).
This raised considerable concern among
ASEAN
governments as
FDI
was a crucial
source of growth, and had helped these countries emerge from the disastrous
economic and political consequences of the mid-1980s recession. The
ASEAN
governments attempted through
AFTA
to offer foreign investors who were increas-
ingly practising a regional division of labour an alternative regional space
of investment and production to China. China by itself offered investors a
potentially competing ‘regional’ investment site in the Asia Pacific region
(Baldwin, 1997: 3), and was regarded by all the core
ASEAN
countries as their
primary competitor for
FDI
. Specifically, it was the tariff liberalisation component
programme of
AFTA
(the Common Effective Preferential Tariff (
CEPT
) scheme)
that members employed to define a distinctive space of production for global
capital in the wider Asia Pacific region. It was thus the growth imperative that
drove the turn to open regionalism in
AFTA
.
240
ATTEMPTING DEVELOPMENTAL REGIONALISM THROUGH AFTA
Yet, when the
ASEAN
Investment Area (
AIA
) was formally adopted as a com-
ponent programme within
AFTA
in October 1998, it stipulated that full market
access and national treatment privileges in the manufacturing sector would be
accorded to
ASEAN
investors by 2010 and to all foreign investors only in 2020.
Later, its coverage was extended to include agriculture, forestry, fisheries and
mining, as well as services incidental to all these sectors. Although the
AIA
programme was accelerated in 1999, only
ASEAN
investors were to be accorded
full market access and national treatment privileges at the earlier dates of 2003 in
manufacturing and 2010 in the other sectors. Foreign (non-
ASEAN
) investors
would receive these benefits only in 2020 as originally scheduled.
Some scholars advise against reading too much into the
AIA
distinction
between
ASEAN
and non-
ASEAN
or foreign investors, since they contend that it is
irrelevant or redundant in the first place because of essentially liberal
FDI
regimes
in
ASEAN
.
10
This argument can be challenged in two ways. First, if the distinction
is indeed irrelevant, the question of why policy makers would choose to make it
in the first place needs to be answered. It is insufficient to assume that policy
makers were acting irrationally or were misinformed, since the implications of
instituting such a distinction were actively debated during the three years of
discussions leading up to the formal adoption of the
AIA
Agreement in 1998,
and continued to be debated from its adoption until September 2001 when this
particular clause was dropped. Clearly, there were some quarters for whom the
distinction was salient. Moreover, when member governments revised the terms
of the
AIA
Agreement in 1999, they continued to privilege
ASEAN
investors over
foreign investors. Second, the argument that the foreign–
ASEAN
distinction is
irrelevant or redundant is easily challenged on empirical grounds. Foreign
investors continued to face investment restrictions in many of the original
ASEAN
countries during the 1990s in selected sectors and in particular policy areas
despite liberalisation of
FDI
regimes, thus making the
AIA
distinction between
domestic and foreign investors significant. This was especially true for the non-
manufacturing sectors where fairly restrictive
FDI
conditions prevailed. These
restrictions ranged from equity ownership conditions, market access to certain
sectors, land ownership regulations, and access to domestic sources of funds.
11
Another possible explanation, and one that can be accommodated within the
open regionalist framework, is that the
AIA
Agreement constituted an additional
tool to reinforce
AFTA
as a means to attract
FDI
to the region. The temporary
discrimination of non-
ASEAN
/foreign investors was simply a way of offering
domestic capital in the different
ASEAN
countries sufficient time to prepare for full
investment liberalisation in 2020. This argument appears to have some merit if
we consider the way the
AIA
Agreement was framed. The original Agreement, in
fact, specified that full market access and national treatment privileges were to be
accorded to all investors immediately where possible, but allowed governments
to maintain temporary exemptions in a variety of sectors and policy areas as they
saw fit (
ASEAN
, 1998).
Yet this does not explain why
ASEAN
investors were allowed full market access
and national treatment privileges 10 years earlier than foreign investors. The
exemptions, which were fairly extensive, were to be removed by 2003 and 2010
for
ASEAN
investors and only in 2020 for all other foreign investors (
ASEAN
,
241
HELEN E S NESADURAI
1998). Such a move would not have protected domestic investors from all
external investors, since other
ASEAN
investors were to be treated as domestic
investors from 2003 or 2010. This suggests that there were other dynamics apart
from the
FDI
dynamic that shaped the development of
AFTA
. As the following
discussion reveals, domestic political priorities, centred on the need to preserve
emerging domestic capital which was politically salient in the face of a different
set of globalisation pressures, also influenced the design of the regional project.
Anticipated changes in multilateral investment rules
Attempts by advanced country governments and their
TNC
s during the 1990s to
develop global rules to lower and remove ‘beyond the border’ barriers to free
trade (Smythe, 2000: 72) constituted a second set of globalisation pressures and
incentives that confronted the
ASEAN
governments. In particular, it was the move
through forums like Asia Pacific Economic Co-operation (
APEC
), the
WTO
and the
OECD
to develop a multilateral regime for investment that would maximise
freedom of operation for foreign investors in as many countries as possible that
was especially salient. Even though these attempts through the
OECD
and
APEC
were unsuccessful, many developing country governments, including those in
ASEAN
, expected guarantees to foreign investors to be written into the
WTO
frame-
work eventually (Khor, 2001: 86).
Although a group of developing countries including Malaysia and Indonesia
successfully kept investment off the negotiating agenda for the First
WTO
Ministerial Meeting in 1996, many governments regarded this reprieve to be only
temporary. These expectations were not misplaced. A working group on invest-
ment was established at the 1996 Ministerial to study the feasibility of incorpo-
rating investment into the
WTO
in the future. In 1998 the
WTO
General Council
decided that the working group should continue its work until the Seattle minis-
terial meeting in 1999 when members would decide on whether to incorporate
investment within the
WTO
(
WTO
, 1998). The European Commission was particu-
larly interested in ensuring that the national treatment principle formed a key part
of any future
WTO
regime on investment (Khor, 2001: 87). Expectations of an
impending global investment regime reinforced perceptions in
ASEAN
of further
intensification of market competition for domestic firms and of the potential
dominance of foreign corporations. They led at least two of the five original
ASEAN
national governments to contemplate providing preferential investment
treatment for
ASEAN
firms in the
AFTA
regional market as a means to build up
domestic firms.
The
ASEAN
response
The concerns about a global free investment regime were strongest in Indonesia
and especially Malaysia and were centred on the future of domestic firms.
Although the Malaysian government had instituted extensive neoliberal
economic reforms from the mid-1980s, the government and the private sector
both saw foreign interest in negotiating global investment rules as posing the
biggest threat to domestic companies.
12
The expectation was that global rules
242
ATTEMPTING DEVELOPMENTAL REGIONALISM THROUGH AFTA
would eventually allow foreign corporations unrestricted access to the domestic
market. Malaysian policy makers had, by the early 1990s, begun to voice their
reservations about the country’s overwhelming dependence on
FDI
and articulated
the importance of nurturing Malaysian multinationals.
13
In response to moves to
include investment on the inaugural
WTO
agenda, Malaysian trade minister
Rafidah Aziz argued against the idea of full market access and national treatment
privileges for foreign investors. She pointed out that such a move would prevent
national governments from implementing ‘national level investment policies …
to enable [domestic firms] to grow and be able to compete with large established
foreign firms’.
14
Indonesia expressed similar concerns, and formally objected to
the inclusion of investment in the
WTO
agenda together with Malaysia and six
other developing countries.
15
Singapore, the most open of the
ASEAN
economies to
FDI
, did not reject the idea of a global investment regime, while the Thai govern-
ment was rather ambivalent on this point.
Using the
AIA
as a developmental tool to nurture domestic capital
In response to concerns about the future of emerging domestic capital, the
Malaysian side advocated a developmental role for the
AIA
that would help to
nurture domestic capital through the privileging of
ASEAN
investors in the
AFTA
market. The single regional market under
AFTA
would provide the necessary scale
and learning economies for domestic firms. Preferential market access and
national treatment privileges for
ASEAN
investors was aimed at providing
domestic (
ASEAN
) firms space to grow and become internationally competitive
before
TNC
s were allowed full investment privileges in the regional market.
16
A
crucial part of this project was also to encourage the development of
ASEAN
conglomerates through joint ventures or other forms of alliances between
ASEAN
investors as a means of competing with the global corporate giants. A senior
official from the
ASEAN
Secretariat explained, ‘the
ASEAN
countries saw the need
to develop
ASEAN
multinationals using the grace period before foreign (non-
ASEAN
) investors would be accorded the same privileges’.
17
Whether the idea of
using the
AIA
as a developmental tool was workable is a separate issue that
cannot be addressed in this paper. Why such a project was adopted is the more
interesting question, to be addressed below.
The Indonesian government explicitly supported the Malaysian position on the
AIA
when then Co-ordinating Minister for the Economy, Ginandjar Kartasasmita,
publicly endorsed in October 1998 the Malaysian suggestion of using the
AIA
to
develop
ASEAN
multinationals and conglomerates that would be globally com-
petitive.
18
Although technocrats from the Commerce Ministry in Thailand found
the privileging of
ASEAN
investors in the
AIA
to be contradictory to
AFTA
’s role as
an instrument to attract
FDI
to
ASEAN
,
19
the Thai government did not reject the
Malaysian suggestion.
20
Neither did Singapore, although it had always advocated
full openness to foreign capital.
In fact, the respective investment agencies in the core
ASEAN
countries accepted
the need to accord investment privileges to
ASEAN
investors in the
AIA
initially
and only later to extend these to non-
ASEAN
investors.
21
This point had, in fact,
been extensively debated during the three years of consultations that led up to the
243
HELEN E S NESADURAI
formal signing of the
AIA
Agreement in October 1998. It had been noted at these
consultations that privileging
ASEAN
investors would be difficult to justify on
economic grounds, since foreign
TNC
s possessed the wealth-creating assets that
the
ASEAN
countries required in order to participate in increasingly sophisticated
global production.
22
Nevertheless, it was also acknowledged that preferential
treatment of
ASEAN
investors could potentially stimulate intra-
ASEAN
investments
and facilitate the emergence and growth of indigenous
ASEAN
multinationals,
which were a necessary vehicle ‘to compete in a world economy increasingly
characterised by globalisation and competition’ (Chia, 1996: 21).
ASEAN
leaders
and policy makers were broadly united on the importance of domestic
firms becoming large and/or multinational as a means of meeting global market
competition.
Where the investment officials differed was on how to define an ‘
ASEAN
’
investor in terms of its minimum
ASEAN
equity share (or maximum foreign equity
share). This was a critical point in the negotiations, since many domestic
investors in the
ASEAN
countries were also involved in joint ventures with foreign
capital. In any case,
FDI
was an important player in
ASEAN
and member govern-
ments were not advocating keeping out
FDI
; they were only interested in
nurturing domestic capital through temporary privileges accorded to the latter,
and particularly in non-manufacturing sectors. Thus developmental regionalism
was to be achieved through the
AIA
without necessarily jeopardising the role of
the
CEPT
tariff liberalisation component of
AFTA
in attracting manufacturing-
sector
FDI
.
Thus it was not surprising that a very open economy like Singapore advocated a
liberal definition of an
ASEAN
investor that stipulated only a minimum 30%
ASEAN
equity share. This meant that any venture up to a maximum foreign equity share of
70% could qualify for national treatment and market access privileges.
23
The Thai
Board of Investment, in contrast, advocated a minimum
ASEAN
equity share of at
least 51%, in keeping with prevailing Thai investment policy, at least during the
initial negotiations on this matter. On the other hand, the Thai Commerce Ministry
that has overall charge of
AFTA
policy and negotiations was more concerned about
emphasising the
AIA
as a tool to attract
FDI
rather than its developmental role. It
was able to pressure the Board to lower the minimum
ASEAN
equity figure to
30%.
24
The other countries, all with varying degrees of restrictions on foreign
participation, preferred a more conservative definition, however. In the end, the
ASEAN
governments agreed to define an
ASEAN
investor as a domestic investor
according to each prospective host country’s local investment laws and policies.
25
Flexibility prevailed for two reasons. First, it allowed individual governments the
independence to adopt mixes of domestic/
ASEAN
and foreign investment that met
national needs. Second, it continued to facilitate joint ventures between foreign
and domestic/
ASEAN
firms as a way of building up the domestic partner through
technology transfer and learning from the foreign partner.
26
Dostları ilə paylaş: |