42
Linda McDowell
the exchange takes place in the market, it is still under-valued, largely because of
its association with the natural attributes of femininity
and so the providers of
care in the market – who are in the main women – are amongst the lowest paid
workers in the labour market.
As well as the association of care with femininity, there is a further attribute of
caring as an economic good that also explains its low rewards in the market. The
provision of care is stubbornly resistant to productivity increases, keeping the cost
of provision high despite the poor pay for employees in this sector. Care by an
individual cannot easily be replaced or substituted
by an alternative form of
provision. It is hard to mechanise caring or to significantly extend the scope of
provision and so there is little potential for economies of scale. As a consequence
most care is provided in what Donath (2000) has termed ‘the other economy’ –
provided by relatives, or through forms of reciprocal exchange, or in informal
relationships – as the purchase of high quality care in the market is beyond the
reach of most families. Feminist economic analysts have thus insisted on an
expansion of the definition of the subject matter of their
respective disciplines to
include work both within the home and in the local community or in the infor-
mal sector: types of work that until recently have not loomed large in the stud-
ies of the nature of production, the allocation of labour or the rise of networked
organisations in advanced industrial economies that largely constitute the subject
matter of contemporary economic geography. Furthermore,
the masculinist lens
that defines work as waged labour in the formal economy sees only part of
the question, providing a partial picture of the current transformations in the
space-economy.
Dostları ilə paylaş: