Stochastic frontier model specifications: Theory usually
presents the producers as successful optimizers by maximizing
production, minimizing cost, and maximizing profits. Econometric
techniques build on the basis to estimate production/cost/profit
function parameters using regression techniques where deviations
of observed choices from optimal ones are modelled as statistical
noise [20]. Therefore, econometric estimation techniques should
allow for the fact that deviations of observed choices from optimal
ones are due to two factors: by either failure to optimize i.e.,
inefficiency or due to random shocks. According to Anonymous
[21] and Mastromarco [22], the econometric approach to estimate
frontier models uses a parametric representation of technology
along with a two-part composed error term. According to Sharma
et al. [23] and Wongnaa & Awunyo Vitor [24] the firm’s technology
is represented by a stochastic production frontier as follows:
;
(
)
=
+
i i i Y f X b e (1)
Where Y
i
denotes output of the i
th
firm; X
i
is a vector of func-
tions of actual input quantities used by the ith firm; β is a vector
of parameters to be estimated; and ε
i
is the composite error term
defined as:
–
=
i i i e v u (2)
where v
i
is assumed to be independently and identically dis-
tributed random errors, independent of the u
i
; and the u
i
is non-
negative random variables, associated with technical inefficiency in
production, which are assumed to be independently and identically
distributed with mean, µ, and variance,
δ
2
u (|N
µ,
δ
2
u|).
Based on the nature of data (cross sectional, panel and time
invariant), the stochastic frontier model has a certain difference
as shown below. In case of cross-section stochastic frontier model
(equation 3) the time dimension of the inefficiency term, u, will be
kept constant over time. Whereas, for panel data stochastic frontier
model (equation 4) time dimension of the inefficiency term, u, will
be allowed to change over time. On the other hand, for time-invari-
ant inefficiency data type (equation 5), inefficiency component of
the error term, u, is time-invariant.
–
i i i i y bx v u α
=
+
+
(3)
–
it i it it it y x v u α
β
=
+
+
1, . . ., ;
1, . . .,
i N t T =
=
(4)
–
it it it i y x v u α
β
=
+
+
1, . . ., ;
1, . . .,
i N t T =
=
(5)
Where, y is the observed outcome (goal attainment), β′x + v is
the optimal, frontier goal (e.g., Maximal production output or min
-
imum cost) pursued by the individual, β′x is the deterministic part
of the frontier and v~N [0, σv2] is randomness or statistical noise
and it is assumed to be normally distributed with zero mean [4]. On
the other hand, the amount by which the observed individual fails
to reach the optimum (the frontier) is u, in this context, u is the “in
-
efficiency.” Moreover, u represents the proportion by which y falls
short of the goal, and has a natural interpretation as proportional
or percentage inefficiency.
So, u=|U| and U~N [0, σu
2
]. Therefore, the economic logic be-
hind this specification is that the production process is subject to
two economically distinguishable random disturbances: statistical
noise represented by viand technical inefficiency represented by u
i
.
The component u
i
is assumed to be distributed independently of vi-
and to satisfy u
i
≥0. The non-negativity of the technical inefficiency
term reflects the fact that if u
i
>0 the country will not produce at the
maximum attainable level.