28
exchange computers and owned by a third party can respond to information more
quickly than other market actors. Profits can therefore be made by a third party
by intervening between a buy and sell order of two other market participants. By
buying the asset from the original seller, holding it for three thousandths of second,
and selling to the first would-be buyer, the computer can profit from any difference
in valuation between the other two actors. The margins are necessarily small, but
if repeated over thousands of transactions, fortunes can be made over a very short
time horizon. In turn these fortunes are paid through higher prices to everyone else
with no productive value added to the economy whatsoever (Davis et al 2016).
The empirical prevalence of this type of activity is striking. Hedge funds, high
frequency traders and propriety traders make up 72 per cent of equity market
turnover in the UK (Kay 2012). In the US, 51 per cent of all transactions are
generated from these types of computer programmes, and 39 per cent in Europe
(World Federation of Exchanges 2013), and a 2010 study showed that managers
trade more than they plan or expect to, despite being aware that the effects
could be damaging for their clients (Guyatt and Lukomnik 2010). The econometric
evidence also appears to show that the propensity for this type of trading has
created a systematic bias towards short-term rewards. Research by Haldane and
Davies at the Bank of England found UK and US stock markets displayed excessive
discounting of risk that was statistically significant in eight of the last nine years
of the study’s panel between 1985 and 2004 (see figure 10). Returns were overly
discounted by around 5 to 10 per cent a year, so that returns on a 30-year time
horizon were typically negligible, despite returns over this time frame being highly
valuable to many savers (Haldane and Davies 2011).
FIGURE 9
UK and US stock markets showed systematic, repeated short-termism before the
financial crisis
Discounting of shares in US and UK stock markets relative to the appropriate time discount,
1985 to 2004
X > 1
X < 1
0.0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1.0
1.2
1.4
1985
1986
198
7
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
199
3
1994
1995
1996
199
7
1998
1999
2000
200
1
2002
2003
2004
Note: Values less than 1 indicate an average discounting of future returns on shares beyond
the appropriate time discount. Coloured years denote those that are statistically significant.
Source: Bank of England 2017
IPPR |
Financing Investment Reforming finance markets for the long-term
29
MISALIGNED INCENTIVES AND AGENCY CAPITALISM
The combination of overly subsidised volume and a culture where relative
performance wins can also lead to a costly over-diversification by asset managers.
As Stephen Davis, Jon Lukomnik and David Pitt-Watson (2016) argue, this enables
fund managers to exploit the rule of averages. As Davis et al observe, a good way
of guaranteeing a high-performing fund that attracts large numbers of investors
is to run so many funds that at least some of them will be high performing. If 64
funds are established then, all else being equal, 32 of them will perform better
than the market average after one year. After six years, the law of probabilities
means that simply by chance you might expect to be left with one fund that has
outperformed the market average in each consecutive year over the period. This
fund will attract inflows of new investments and assets along the way, while the
poorer performing funds can be discontinued and restarted with a clean historical
record. So long as an asset manager has a number of ‘high performing’ funds, they
will retain and attract clients and the cost of multiple lower performing funds will
be subsidised by the asset based fee they accrue. Some variation and diversity of
funds is important, but the current number of funds reported on by Morningstar
alone is in excess of 53,000 (Davis et al 2016). By contrast, the average defined
contribution pension schemes tends to have no more than 25 investment options,
which would suggest the limit to which the ‘investible universe’ can helpfully be
divided is significantly below 53,000 (Ibid).
This phenomenon is sometimes described as ‘agency capitalism’. Multiple small
misalignments in incentives are driven by rewarding intermediators based
on volume and relative – rather than absolute – performance. This in turn is
exacerbated by derivatives, which can insure the owners of shares against risk.
This means that not only can the main traders in equity be largely uninterested
in the underlying value of the shares they own, but beneficial share ownership
can also be entirely decoupled from the economic interest of a share – leading
to conflicts of interest (Ibid). As such, misalignments in incentives aggregate to a
system-wide effect where the owners of shares are ‘rationally reticent’ to actively
nurture and improve the fundamental value of the companies whose shares they
trade on behalf of savers (Gilson and Gordon 2013). Intermediaries that are paid
for the frequency of their activity over short time horizons, and are insured against
the economic risks they take, are not incentivised to steward UK companies to
create long-term value.
Academic work on company takeovers gives further evidence on the negative
impacts of agency capitalism. Standard economic theory might suggest that a
‘market’ in company takeovers would provide incentives to improve economic
efficiency (Romano 1992). However, the empirical evidence suggests that there is
statistically no difference between firms that are bought out or not bought out,
other than that acquired firms tend to be smaller than non-acquired firms. Firms
seeking to avoid takeover, then, are incentivised to increase their size, not their
long-term profitability (Hughes and Singh 1987, Cosh and Hughes 2008).
Agency capitalism appears to have had a measurable effect on those investors
who use the services of asset managers. Despite surveys showing that trust is the
most important factor against which asset managers are judged, just 39 per cent of
investors in the UK think that the industry as a whole can be trusted to serve their
interests (CFA Institute and Edelman 2013).
From the point of view of savers, workers and society as a whole, the danger
of misaligned incentives in equity markets is that they shape the governance
decisions of the UK’s major firms, making them more short-term and less inclined
to invest in long-term value creation. This appears to be happening through two
important transmission mechanisms: shareholder ballots and CEO remuneration.
Voting at the annual meeting of companies can have a tremendous effect on
IPPR |
Financing Investment Reforming finance markets for the long-term
30
absolute value. Ballots elect directors, who in turn appoint the CEO, but they can
also determine rewards policy for executive staff and decisions over mergers and
acquisitions (Davis et al 2016). However, there is a measurable lack of engagement
in asserting ownership rights through voting. Individual investors, who make up
more than a quarter of beneficial owners, only realise around 29 per cent of their
voting potential. Institutional investors utilise 90 per cent of their votes, but many
of these rely on the intermediation chain. This is concerning because despite
employing hundreds of people, the largest asset managers devote just four people
on average to conducting analysis in support of voting decisions. This equates to
one person making the decision to appoint 50 directors every working day of the
year (ibid). In part this is due to a reliance on proxy voting companies. But this in
turn raises concerns, given that transparency and accountability for the advice
these companies give is widely thought to be lacking (Waygood 2014).
CEO remuneration is the second important transmission mechanism for ‘market
myopia’ to enter corporate priorities in corporate governance decisions. The
inclusion of share options in CEO and board remuneration packages is intended
to align company leadership with shareholders. However, there is considerable
evidence that this approach fails to align incentives properly. Creative
accountancy, and the backdating of options, help to decouple even short-term
executive performance from their rewards (Bebchuk and Fried 2006). But more
fundamentally, even where incentives are aligned with beneficial owners, this
enables the short-term horizons of equity intermediaries to gain purchase in the
board room. Share ownership for the median FTSE 100 CEO is worth 200 per cent
of base salary, and 25 per cent of CEOs own shares worth more than 300 per cent
of salary (PWC 2012) (see figure 11). Crucially, executives also display excessive
short termism. Survey evidence shows that more CEOs would opt for £250,000
paid to them tomorrow than £450,000 in three years’ time. This equates to a
discount rate of 20 per cent, compared with a ‘rational’ rate of around 8.5 per
cent (Haldane and Davies 2011).
FIGURE 10
Senior employees of UK publically listed firms have a significant economic interest in
the stock market
Proportion (per cent of base salary) of share ownership by job type among FTSE 250 and FTSE
100 firms, 2011
Upper quartile
Median
Lower quartile
0%
50%
100%
150%
200%
250%
300%
350%
ExCo
Main
board
CEO
Source: PWC 2012
These transmission mechanisms appear to be affecting business decisions.
Econometric analysis of the empirical evidence in the US showed that companies
that fall just short of their earnings targets would also cut spending on R&D and
IPPR |
Financing Investment Reforming finance markets for the long-term
31
intangibles, while firms that just miss their targets see a decline in their stock
market valuation (Terry 2014). Further evidence from the US has shown that more
than 90 per cent of the largest firms remunerate their highest-paid employees
for their performance over a time horizon of three years or less, despite the fact
that any investment in (say) R&D would likely take far longer to bear commercial
advantages (IRRC Institute and Organizational Capital Partners 2014). A survey
of more than 400 executives also found that 75 per cent would sacrifice positive
economic outcomes if it helped smooth short-term earnings: that is, actively
rejecting highly profitable projects if it affected quarterly expectations. And this
was reported to be driven explicitly by the desire to satisfy the expectations of the
intermediary institutions trading their shares (Graham et al 2005).
SUPPORTING RESPONSIBLE STEWARDSHIP
The evidence strongly suggests therefore that the chain of intermediation in equity
markets disrupts and misaligns incentives between savers and company boards
which, in turn, contributes to lower levels of investment and long-term value
creation by UK firms. Underlying this misalignment of incentives are two important
dynamics, in which intermediaries are paid for relative performance, and the
volume of activity, rather than for nurturing productive long-term investment.
Critical to this problem are the short time horizons over which intermediaries
accrue rewards through trading shares. To correct these dynamics, we propose
a dual strategy, to change the rules by which equity markets operate, using both
legal and tax reform.
Our analysis has shown that too much activity is rewarded for relative
performance over a short time horizon. Our proposal therefore is that regulators
take a system-wide view in order to demand, support and nurture a realignment of
incentives between intermediaries and citizen savers.
As the first step, we propose that government strengthens and extends the legal
fiduciary duty that applies to actors in finance markets.
Over recent years many sensible reforms have been recommended by a
number of institutions, governments and market actors to correct ‘market
failures’ and to enhance ‘active stewardship’. These range from boosting
transparency with new disclosure guidelines for derivative ownership or
new performance metrics for asset managers to shifting away from quarterly
targets and short-term remuneration packages for CEOs. We agree that the
approach needs to be multi-pronged and inventive. However, regulation that
is overly prescriptive and rigid will be ill-equipped to keep pace with fluid
and complex financial practices and strategies. The new regulatory strategy,
therefore, should take a systemic view rather than reaching a system-wide
effect through the sum of multiple individual parts.
We therefore propose that government inserts a spine of legally enforceable
responsibility right the way through the intermediation chain. To do this, the
legal provision for ensuring that trustees act in the interests of savers should be
strengthened, clarified and – most importantly – extended to intermediaries. This
legal provision is called fiduciary law, or the ‘fiduciary principle’. Fiduciary law
requires that agents representing the interests of others take every reasonable
step to ensure their actions do in fact result in the best value to the ultimate
client. Unlike contractual law, which governs the issuance of loans, fiduciary law
allows for agent discretion in interpreting the interests of their clients. This is
essential for allowing experts to use their skills and experience efficiently on
behalf of clients.
At present, the legal fiduciary responsibilities of a trustee, such as a pension fund,
does not pass automatically to the intermediaries to whom they might contract
IPPR |
Financing Investment Reforming finance markets for the long-term
32
or delegate tasks. Echoing the recommendation of both the Kay and the Law
Commission’s separate reviews (2012 and 2014 respectively) for government, we
propose:
•
first, that the obligations and powers of fiduciary responsibility must remain
with a trustee even if intermediaries are contracted to act on their behalf
•
second, that the legal reach of fiduciary responsibility is extended to asset
managers and brokers in the intermediary chain.
Such an extension of the fiduciary principle will require independent oversight
and interpretation. Our proposal is the establishment of a new public body, the
Responsible Ownership Commission (ROC), which in the first instance would
examine how the fiduciary principle should be extended and defined for 21st
century equity markets. Following the model of the Financial Services Council in
Australia, the ROC should also recommend explicit broader environmental and
social obligations under fiduciary responsibility. The ROC should also provide an
ongoing monitoring, supporting and enforcement role. This could include training
and consultancy for asset managers and financial analysts, a detailed framework
for obligatory information disclosure (such as of derivative ownership and sell-
side analysis), an independent complaints procedure, and the power to name,
shame and fine for non-compliance those failing to meet fiduciary and disclosure
requirements. The ROC should also be seen as the first regulatory response, not
the last: In due course the ROC would itself make recommendations to government
for further, individual reforms necessary to meet its systemic objectives. These
might include proposals such as weighted voting power for longer ownership or a
maximum number of firms in an investment portfolio.
TAX REFORM – HARDWIRING NEW INCENTIVES
We propose two tax reforms specifically designed to reverse the dynamics which
underlie the misalignment of incentives in equity markets: excess turnover and
short-term ownership of shares. The reforms, taken together, would be broadly
cost neutral. They involve:
•
extending stamp duty reserve tax
•
tapering capital gains tax for long-term share ownership.
Over recent years there have been growing calls for the introduction of a type
of financial transaction tax in the UK (Seely 2014). But much of this debate tends
to overlook that the UK already has a financial transaction tax, known as stamp
duty reserve tax (SDRT). SDRT is one of the oldest, best established and cheapest
taxes to administer in the UK. At present, a charge of 0.5 per cent is levied on
the purchase of shares at the point of certifying a legal transition in ownership.
Revenues from this tax are consistently worth between £3 and £4 billion per
year, with 90 per cent of this collected automatically via the central securities
depository computer. The tax is exceedingly hard to avoid because it is levied on
the ‘issuance principle’: no matter where you are in the world, you have to pay the
tax if you register for legal ownership of a share issued by a UK-based company.
This is why 50 per cent of revenue is successfully collected from non-UK residents.
Notwithstanding its impressive effectiveness from HMRC's point of view, SDRT
has not been updated for three decades, even though the nature of financial
intermediation has changed and expanded hugely in that time (Persaud 2017).
In principle, anyone seeking to register legal ownership over a share issued
by a UK-based firm must pay the SDRT. At present, however, exemptions on
SDRT are made for intermediaries regarded as ‘market makers’: the asset
managers and hedge funds that seemingly generate liquidity in equity markets
by deliberately contributing to increased share turnover. Historically, this type
of activity accounted for around 15 per cent of transactions, but the growth in
IPPR |
Financing Investment Reforming finance markets for the long-term
33
the intermediation chain now means that 40-50 per cent of share turnover is
eligible for exemption (ibid). Despite this, increased turnover has been shown
not to improve liquidity when it is most needed (Huang and Wang 2010). Liquidity
is provided not by the volume of transactions, but by diversity in buy and sell
strategies. A review of the evidence shows that because of the homogeneity of
strategies from high-frequency traders – as they all seek short-term returns from
large volumes of trades – the recent increases in turnover have mainly served to
add to liquidity when it is already in excess, but reduce it when it is in short supply
(Persaud 2017).
Borrowing from the detailed work by the financial economist, Avinash Persaud,
we propose that incentives for excess trading should be reduced by replacing
the 100 per cent relief on SDRT for intermediaries with a new rate of 0.2 per cent.
IPPR analysis of Persaud’s (2017) own estimates for non-tax transaction costs,
and the rate of elasticity in demand with respect to an increase in costs, suggests
that introducing a new 0.2 per cent rate of SDRT for market makers would reduce
turnover generated by intermediaries by around 60 per cent, and overall turnover
in equity markets by about a quarter to a third. The reform would therefore have a
significant effect in reducing short-term equity trading. At a conservative estimate,
these reforms would also generate new revenue worth around £1.2 billion by the
2020s (IPPR analysis using OBR 2017 and Persuad 2017).
This would be in line with recent experiences in France (2013) and Italy (2012).
From a position of not previously charging stamp duty on shares at all, both
countries have introduced more far-reaching taxes than the UK’s SDRT, albeit at a
lower rate. Both countries introduced tax rates of 0.1 per cent on shares, 0.01 per
cent on equity derivatives and 0.01 per cent on cancelled trades. Together these
have resulted in a reduction in turnover of around 20 per cent (Persaud 2017).
Crucially, however, a detailed study of the effects in France found that liquidity in
the market was not reduced as a result (Capelle-Blancard and O Havrylchyk 2013).
In order to strengthen its effects, the revenue raised from extending SDRT to
reduce excessive volumes of trade could be used to incentivise the longer-term
holding of shares. It would be possible to extend reliefs for capital gains tax (CGT)
and corporation tax for company equities so they become more generous the
longer a share has been owned. This would provide a marginal incentive to hold
shares for longer. To the extent that it was successful, rational, longer term owners
would be expected to adjust their calculations over the implied discounting of
longer-term gains and therefore become more interested in the underlying value
of the companies they own.
A number of countries, such as the US, France and Austria, have reliefs on CGT,
especially for equity, that apply if an asset has been owned for more than a given
number of years. Between 1998 and 2008 the UK also had a relief on business
assets that halved the rate of capital gains tax after one year and two years
(cumulatively). Although these systems showed some success, they also introduce
dramatic cliffs in the tax schedule, offering significant discounts at the point a
share is owned for more than one or two years. This can have perverse effects on
behaviour, such as market actors selling shares on the day they become eligible
for a considerably lower rate of CGT. To counteract this problem, we propose a
formula-based tax rate that gradually tapers away the rate of CGT on corporate
equity as a function of length of ownership. At the same time, we also propose a
form of allowance for corporate equity (ACE) in UK corporation tax that becomes
progressively more generous the longer a share is owned (for an introduction
to the ACE literature see relevant chapters from Mirrlees et al 2011). Such an
allowance would have the advantage, not only of incentivising longer ownership of
shares, but also lowering the cost of equity finance for firms looking to invest.
|