28
As a result of the priorities given to state firms in financial markets, large capital-intensive
firms have been favored relative to small, medium-sized and labor-intensive firms.
42
Indeed, according to estimates by the People’s Bank of China (2004), small and medium-
sized firms received less than ten percent of the bank loans in the early 21
st
century,
although they produced more than half of GDP.
43
There is a multitude of explanations of
why the state banks favor large firms, such as lower perceived risk (because of implicit
government guarantees on the loans to large firms) and political pressure from local
authorities that fear severe employment problems if large firms run into financial
difficulties. The alleged discrimination of SMEs in financial markets has, of course, also
considerably disfavored private firms, and hence indirectly the
service sector, both of
which are generally regarded as disfavored also in other ways, for example by various
regulations, including the allocation of land-lease contracts, building permits, etc. (World
Bank, 2003b). The emergence and expansion of informal financial markets have, of
course, mitigated the distortions of the allocation of resources brought about by
deficiencies in formal financial markets. However, the development of informal financial
markets cannot possibly have eliminated the distortions, since
the duality of financial
markets in itself is a distortion, reflected in different levels of interest rates.
The large resource costs of the growth path in China are also reflected in the high
investment ratio, about 43 percent of GDP in recent years (“fixed capital formation”).
This reflects not only the exceptionally large industrial sector (about 46 percent of
GDP) but also the high capital-output ratio
within
that sector.
44
By comparison, during
similar development phases, Hong Kong, Taiwan/China, and South
Korea grew nearly
as fast, with smaller investment ratios (about 35 percent of GDP). The high capital
intensity in China is also reflected in the relatively high marginal capital/output ratio –
in the interval of 4-5, while more “normal” ratios are 2.5 to 3.5.
45
The marginal capital/
output ratio has also increased during the last decade in connection with a rise in the
investment share from 35 percent of GDP in the mid-1990s. It is tempting to interpret
42
SMEs are defined in China as enterprises with between 8 and 2.000 employees, less than US $ 50
million assets, and less than US $ 37 million sales. 80 percent of these firms are estimated to have been
privately owned in 2001 according to Citybank.
43
For similar calculations, see McKinsey (2006, Exhibit 3.5).
44
As in many other developing countries, this figure may be biased upward because statistics are likely
to be more complete on investment spending than on GDP. Presumably, the revision of the national
accounts reported in December 2005 has taken care of this problem, at least to some extent.
45
With an investment ratio of 0.45, the marginal capital/output ratio is 4.7 when GDP growth is 9.5
percent.
29
this as a fall in the macroeconomic return on real investment
46
--
a fall to be expected
when the capital stock rises extremely rapidly.
The large aggregate investment in real capital assets may be compared with the
modest spending on education, which is often reported to be 4-5 percent of GDP
(4.3 percent according to the OECD, 2006), of which 2.7 percentage points are
financed by the public sector.
47
It is unlikely that these proportions can be
rationalized with reference to the relative returns on these two types of
investments
48
.
Hence, there is probably a general efficiency argument for
reallocating spending from (aggregate) investment in physical assets to (aggregate)
education in China,
a point made, for instance, by James Heckman (2005). In
principle, resources could then be freed for the consumption of both ordinary
consumer goods and human services, such as health care, without jeopardizing fast
GDP growth. (Today, private consumption is not more than 40 percent of GDP.)
49
The modest size of the service sector is often regarded as another indicator of
inefficiencies in the allocation of resources across production sectors in China. This
point has recently been weakened, although
not eliminated, by revisions of the
national accounts (in December 2005), whereby the reported GDP share of services
was raised from 32 percent to 41 percent – still, however, a fairly modest figure for
a country at China’s current stage of development.
Naturally, China’s capital-intensive growth strategy has also constrained the ability
of non-agricultural sectors to absorb the surplus labor in agriculture. This helps
46
McKinsey Global Institute (2006, Exhibit 3.23) calculates that the marginal capital/output ratio has
increased from 3.30 in the first half of the 1990s to 4.9 after 2001.
47
Revised national accounts 2005, and UNDP (2005 Figure 3.9).
48
Studies of the return on secondary and tertiary education in China in recent years, based on wage
differentials, usually give returns in the interval 7-8.5 percent. A recent study by Zhang et al. (2005)
concludes that the return on education has increased from 4.0 percent per year of schooling in 1988 to
10.2 percent in 2001. By contrast, a twin-study (to avoid selection bias due to innate ability) gives lower
figures (Li et al., 2005), basically because of an asserted zero return on high school education, which the
author asserts to function just as a device for screening ability. By contrast, one more year of
Dostları ilə paylaş: