36
small societies” (Xiaoyi, 1996).
61
Besides these arrangements by firms, public-sector
authorities provided social assistance and care to some of the urban
three no’s
(individuals with no working ability, no family, and no income).
Although both cash benefits and publicly provided human services were much less
prevalent and generous in rural areas, agricultural communes did provide both job
guarantees (with job obligations) and some arrangements for basic sanitation, simple
health care (largely by “barefoot doctors”) and elementary education. Moreover, under the
so-called
wu bao hu
system, rural collective organizations
provided some benefits and
care also for elderly and disabled individuals without family support.
Since government authorities during this period were responsible for major production
and investment decisions (a rough type of input-output planning) we may, with some
overstatement, say that the division of tasks between the government and the work units
in China was just about the reverse of the corresponding division in developed countries
today, where firms are in charge of production and investment, and the government
(particularly in Western Europe) runs most of the social arrangements.
Before the economic reforms, the budgets of individual SOEs were to a considerable
extent integrated with the government budget: the surpluses (profits) of individual firms
were delivered to the central government budget, and the government covered their losses.
Some of the social costs borne by individual SOEs were therefore pooled across the
nation as a whole. Thus, the financing of the social arrangements in urban areas formally
resembled high (close to 100 percent) profit taxes with “full loss-offset”. However, wages
were kept down to generate sufficiently high profits to finance these social benefits. It
may therefore be more appropriate to say that the financing of
social spending in urban
areas,
in fact
, was largely equivalent to payroll taxes with the incidence on wage
earners.
62
It is easy to understand why the economic reforms rendered these social arrangements
dysfunctional. Benefits tied to specific work units simply do not sit well in a market
61
There is an obvious parallel with the social role of some large firms in small towns (“company
towns”) during the early industrialization period in today’s developed countries.
62
Before the economic reforms, the social costs of firms seem to have been about the same size as the
wage bill; see Hussain, 2000a, p. 70.
37
economy, since an efficiently functioning labor market requires social benefits to be
portable. At the same time, the market risks increased for employees as a result of
recurrent structural changes and related job losses. New high-risk economic agents, such
as private entrepreneurs and the self-employed, also emerged. Moreover, while the
previous agricultural communes, many of which comprised thousands of households,
could achieve
some pooling of income risk, family farms cannot easily do so – at the
same time as new market risks emerged for the farm population as well.
During an early phase of the reform period, the decline in firms’ financial surplus also
made it difficult for many of them to live up to their social responsibilities.
63
In Chinese
parlance, work units “no longer guarantee either the iron rice bowl or the iron chair”
(Warner and Zhu, 2000) – a formulation referring to the fact that firms were no longer
able to take responsibility for either income or jobs.
Ad hoc
selective subsidies and soft
loans to state-owned firms with financial problems functioned as a “stop-gap solution” to
the problem. In other words, loans by state banks have to some extent functioned as a
substitute for traditional social policies. As a result, the discrimination of private firms in
credit and capital markets was accentuated, which further reduced
their ability to expand
production and employment. The “double bind” – state firms constrained in shedding
labor, and private firms constrained in acquiring loans – has entailed a kind of catch-22
situation during much of the reform period. It is difficult to remove this “double bind”
until non-state firms can expand their employment sufficiently to absorb a much larger
fraction of the redundant labor force, and before a more comprehensive system of income
security is in place.
64
Inadvertently, households have also helped finance firms’ social obligations, since
households’ deposits in state banks (at low, and during some periods even negative, real
interest rates) have been intermediated into loans to state firms. As a result, the social
63
According to official statistics, the financial surplus is reported to have fallen from about 20 percent of
firms’ aggregate revenues in 1978 to about 4 percent in 2003 (Chinese Statistical Yearbook, 1996 and
2004). There has, however, probably been a substantial recovery of these
surpluses from about year
2000; see, for instance the survey of papers on this issue in The Economist, 2006, October 21. Agarwala
(2004) has argued that statistics of surpluses (or profits) in Chinese firms are not fully comparable with
statistics in western countries, largely because investment spending in China is not periodized in the
same way.
64
Although the employment level in the non-state sector in urban areas has increased considerably, from
12 to 43 million between 1990 and 2003 (Chinese Statistical Yearbook, 1990-2004), this has clearly not
been sufficient to absorb redundant workers in state-owned firms and collective firms, new entrants into
the labor force, and the flow (in particular the potential flow) of labor from agriculture.
38
obligations of state firms have, in fact, been partly financed by an “inflation tax” on
households’ financial saving (although less so during years with low inflation). This, in
turn, implies that much of the real return on household saving has been transferred to the
beneficiaries of various social arrangements – much like a tax-financed pay-as-you-go
(“paygo”) system, although in this case the “tax” was imposed on the return on saving
rather than on work.
Moreover, fewer and fewer workers are employed in firms with explicit social
responsibilities. One reason is the lay-offs of workers in state firms (about a third of the
initial work force from the peak level), another is the increased
number of employees in
private firms without similar social responsibilities.
65
Indeed, among the 260 million
regular workers in urban areas (with urban
hukou
status) in 2005, no more than between
110 and 150 million, or 40-60 percent, seem to be covered by social insurance
arrangements (depending on which specific arrangements we have in mind).
These developments are important background factors for recent attempts to reform the
social arrangements. Before I turn to China’s policy options in this field (Section III), it is,
however, useful to highlight some recent social developments in the country.
Dostları ilə paylaş: