CHAPTER
10
The Federal Reserve:
Why that dollar in your pocket is more than just a piece of paper
S
ometimes simple statements speak loudly. On September 11, 2001, hours after
the terrorist attacks on the United States, the Federal Reserve issued the
following statement: “The Federal Reserve System is open and operating. The
discount window is available to meet liquidity needs.”
Those terse and technical two sentences had a calming effect on global
markets. The following Monday, as America’s markets opened for their first
trading sessions after the attack, the Federal Reserve cut interest rates by 0.5
percent, another act that moderated the financial and economic impact of the
terrorist assaults.
How exactly does an inelegant two-sentence statement have such a profound
effect on the world’s largest economy—indeed, on the whole global economy?
The Federal Reserve has tools with more direct impact on the global economy
than any other institution in the world, public or private. During the economic
crisis that began to unfold in 2007, the Federal Reserve used everything in that
toolkit—and then acquired some new gadgets—to wrestle the financial system
back from the brink of panic. Since then, some have criticized the Fed and its
chairman, Ben Bernanke, for doing too much; some have criticized the Fed for
doing too little. Everyone agrees that what the Fed does matters enormously.
From where does the Federal Reserve, an institution that is not directly
accountable to the voting public, derive such power? And how does that power
affect the lives of everyday Americans? The answer to all those questions is the
same: The Federal Reserve controls the money supply and therefore the credit
tap for the economy. When that tap is open wide, interest rates fall and we spend
more freely on things that require borrowed money—everything from new cars
to new manufacturing plants. Thus, the Fed can use monetary policy to
counteract economic downturns (or prevent them in the first place). And it can
inject money into the financial system after sudden shocks, such as the 1987
stock market crash or the terrorist attacks of September 11 or the bursting of the
American real estate bubble, when consumers and firms might otherwise freeze
in place and stop spending. Or the Fed can tighten the tap by raising interest
rates. When the cost of borrowed funds goes up, our spending slows. It is an
awesome power. Paul Krugman once wrote, “If you want a simple model for
predicting the unemployment rate in the United States over the next few years,
here it is: It will be what Greenspan wants it to be, plus or minus a random error
reflecting the fact that he is not quite God.” The same is now true of Ben
Bernanke.
God does not have to manage by committee; Ben Bernanke does. The Federal
Reserve System is made up of twelve Reserve Banks spread across the country
and a seven-person board of governors based in Washington. Ben Bernanke is
chairman of the board of governors—he’s the “Fed chairman.” The Federal
Reserve regulates commercial banks, supports the banking infrastructure, and
generally makes the plumbing of the financial system work. Those jobs require
competence, not genius or great foresight. Monetary policy, the Federal
Reserve’s other responsibility, is different. It might reasonably be described as
the economic equivalent of brain surgery. Economists do not agree on how the
Federal Reserve ought to manage our money supply. Nor do they even agree on
exactly how or why changes in the money supply have the effects that they do.
Yet economists do agree that effective monetary policy matters; the Fed must
feed just the right amount of credit to the economy to keep it growing steadily.
Getting it wrong can have disastrous consequences. Robert Mundell, winner of
the 1999 Nobel Prize in Economics, has argued that bungled monetary policy in
the 1920s and 1930s caused chronic deflation that destabilized the world. He has
argued, “Had the price of gold been raised in the late 1920s, or, alternatively,
had the major central banks pursued policies of price stability instead of
adhering to the gold standard, there would have been no Great Depression, no
Nazi revolution, and no World War II.”
1
The job would not appear to be that complicated. If the Fed can make the
economy grow faster by lowering interest rates, then presumably lower interest
rates are always better. Indeed, why should there be any limit to the rate at which
the economy can grow? If we begin to spend more freely when rates are cut
from 7 percent to 5 percent, why stop there? If there are still people without jobs
and others without new cars, then let’s press on to 3 percent, or even 1 percent.
New money for everyone! Sadly, there are limits to how fast any economy can
grow. If low interest rates, or “easy money,” causes consumers to demand 5
percent more new PT Cruisers than they purchased last year, then Chrysler must
expand production by 5 percent. That means hiring more workers and buying
more steel, glass, electrical components, etc. At some point, it becomes difficult
or impossible for Chrysler to find these new inputs, particularly qualified
workers. At that point, the company simply cannot make enough PT Cruisers to
satisfy consumer demand; instead, the company begins to raise prices.
Meanwhile, autoworkers recognize that Chrysler is desperate for labor, and the
union demands higher wages.
The story does not stop there. The same thing would be happening throughout
the economy, not just at Chrysler. If interest rates are exceptionally low, firms
will borrow to invest in new computer systems and software; consumers will
break out their VISA cards for big-screen televisions and Caribbean cruises—all
up to a point. When the cruise ships are full and Dell is selling every computer it
can produce, then those firms will raise their prices, too. (When demand exceeds
supply, firms can charge more and still fill every boat or sell every computer.) In
short, an “easy money” policy at the Fed can cause consumers to demand more
than the economy can produce. The only way to ration that excess demand is
with higher prices. The result is inflation.
The sticker price on the PT Cruiser goes up, and no one is better off for it.
True, Chrysler is taking in more money, but it is also paying more to its
suppliers and workers. Those workers are seeing higher wages, but they are also
paying higher prices for their basic needs. Numbers are changing everywhere,
but the productive capacity of our economy and the measure of our well-being,
real GDP, has hit the wall. Once started, the inflationary cycle is hard to break.
Firms and workers everywhere begin to expect continually rising prices (which,
in turn, causes continually rising prices). Welcome to the 1970s.
The pace at which the economy can grow without causing inflation might
reasonably be considered a “speed limit.” After all, there are only a handful of
ways to increase the amount that we as a nation can produce. We can work
longer hours. We can add new workers, through falling unemployment or
immigration (recognizing that the workers available may not have the skills in
demand). We can add machines and other kinds of capital that help us to
produce things. Or we can become more productive—produce more with what
we already have, perhaps because of an innovation or a technological change.
Each of these sources of growth has natural constraints. Workers are scarce;
capital is scarce; technological change proceeds at a finite and unpredictable
pace. In the late 1990s, American autoworkers threatened to go on strike because
they were being forced to work too much overtime. (Don’t we wish we had that
problem now…) Meanwhile, fast-food restaurants were offering signing bonuses
to new employees. We were at the wall. Economists reckon that the speed limit
of the American economy is somewhere in the range of 3 percent growth per
year.
The phrase “somewhere in the range” gives you the first inkling of how hard
the Fed’s job is. The Federal Reserve must strike a delicate balance. If the
economy grows more slowly than it is capable of, then we are wasting economic
potential. Plants that make PT Cruisers sit idle; the workers who might have jobs
there are unemployed instead. An economy that has the capacity to grow at 3
percent instead limps along at 1.5 percent, or even slips into recession. Thus, the
Fed must feed enough credit to the economy to create jobs and prosperity but not
so much that the economy begins to overheat. William McChesney Martin, Jr.,
Federal Reserve chairman during the 1950s and 1960s, once noted that the Fed’s
job is to take away the punch bowl just as the party gets going.
Or sometimes the Fed must rein in the party long after it has gone out of
control. The Federal Reserve has deliberately engineered a number of recessions
in order to squeeze inflation out of the system. Most notably, Fed chairman Paul
Volcker was the ogre who ended the inflationary party of the 1970s. At that
point, naked people were dancing wildly on the tables. Inflation had climbed
from 3 percent in 1972 to 13.5 percent in 1980. Mr. Volcker hit the monetary
brakes, meaning that he cranked up interest rates to slow the economy down.
Short-term interest rates peaked at over 16 percent in 1981. The result was a
painful unwinding of the inflationary cycle. With interest rates in double digits,
there were plenty of unsold Chrysler K cars sitting on the lot. Dealers were
forced to cut prices (or stop raising them). The auto companies idled plants and
laid off workers. The autoworkers who still had jobs decided that it would be a
bad time to ask for more money.
The same thing, of course, was going on in every other sector of the economy.
Slowly, and at great human cost, the expectation that prices would steadily rise
was purged from the system. The result was the recession of 1981–1982, during
which GDP shrank by 3 percent and unemployment climbed to nearly 10
percent. In the end, Mr. Volcker did clear the dancers off the tables. By 1983,
inflation had fallen to 3 percent. Obviously it would have been easier and less
painful if the party had never gone out of control in the first place.
Where does the Fed derive this extraordinary power over interest rates? After all,
commercial banks are private entities. The Federal Reserve cannot force
Citibank to raise or lower the rates it charges consumers for auto loans and home
mortgages. Rather, the process is indirect. Recall from Chapter 7 that the interest
rate is really just a rental rate for capital, or the “price of money.” The Fed
controls America’s money supply. We’ll get to the mechanics of that process in
a moment. For now, recognize that capital is no different from apartments: The
greater the supply, the cheaper the rent. The Fed moves interest rates by making
changes in the quantity of funds available to commercial banks. If banks are
awash with money, then interest rates must be relatively low to attract borrowers
for all the available funds. When capital is scarce, the opposite will be true:
Banks can charge higher interest rates and still attract enough borrowers for all
available funds. It’s supply and demand, with the Fed controlling the supply.
These monetary decisions—the determination whether interest rates need to
go up, down, or stay the same—are made by a committee within the Fed called
the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC), which consists of the board of
governors, the president of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, and the
presidents of four other Federal Reserve Banks on a rotating basis. The Fed
chairman is also the chairman of the FOMC. Ben Bernanke derives his power
from the fact that he is sitting at the head of the table when the FOMC makes
interest rate decisions.
If the FOMC wants to stimulate the economy by lowering the cost of
borrowing, the committee has two primary tools at its disposal. The first is the
discount rate, which is the interest rate at which commercial banks can borrow
funds directly from the Federal Reserve. The relationship between the discount
rate and the cost of borrowing at Citibank is straightforward; when the discount
rate falls, banks can borrow more cheaply from the Fed and therefore lend more
cheaply to their customers. There is one complication. Borrowing directly from
the Fed carries a certain stigma; it implies that a bank was not able to raise funds
privately. Thus, turning to the Fed for a loan is similar to borrowing from your
parents after about age twenty-five: You’ll get the money, but it’s better to look
somewhere else first.
Instead, banks generally borrow from other banks. The second important tool
in the Fed’s money supply kit is the federal funds rate, the rate that banks charge
other banks for short-term loans. The Fed cannot stipulate the rate at which
Wells Fargo lends money to Citigroup. Rather, the FOMC sets a target for the
federal funds rate, say 4.5 percent, and then manipulates the money supply to
accomplish its objective. If the supply of funds goes up, then banks will have to
drop their prices—lower interest rates—to find borrowers for the new funds.
One can think of the money supply as a furnace with the federal funds rate as its
thermostat. If the FOMC cuts the target fed funds rate from 4.5 percent to 4.25
percent, then the Federal Reserve will pump money into the banking system
until the rate Wells Fargo charges Citigroup for an overnight loan falls to
something very close to 4.25 percent.
All of which brings us to our final conundrum: How does the Federal Reserve
inject money into a private banking system? Does Ben Bernanke print $100
million of new money, load it into a heavily armored truck, and drive it to a
Citibank branch? Not exactly—though that image is not a bad way to understand
what does happen.
Ben Bernanke and the FOMC do create new money. In the United States, they
alone have that power. (The Treasury merely mints new currency and coins to
replace money that already exists.) The Federal Reserve does deliver new money
to banks like Citibank. But the Fed does not give funds to the bank; it trades the
new money for government bonds that the banks currently own. In our
metaphorical example, the Citibank branch manager meets Ben Bernanke’s
armored truck outside the bank, loads $100 million of new money into the
bank’s vault, and then hands the Fed chairman $100 million in government
bonds from the bank’s portfolio in return. Note that Citibank has not been made
richer by the transaction. The bank has merely swapped $100 million of one kind
of asset (bonds) for $100 million of a different kind of asset (cash, or, more
accurately, its electronic equivalent).
Banks hold bonds for the same reason individual investors do; bonds are a
safe place to park funds that aren’t needed for something else. Specifically,
banks buy bonds with depositors’ funds that are not being loaned out. To the
economy, the fact that Citibank has swapped bonds for cash makes all the
difference. When a bank has $100 million of deposits parked in bonds, those
funds are not being loaned out. They are not financing houses, or businesses, or
new plants. But after Ben Bernanke’s metaphorical armored truck pulls away,
Citibank is left holding funds that can be loaned out. That means new loans for
all the kinds of things that generate economic activity. Indeed, money injected
into the banking system has a cascading effect. A bank that swaps bonds for
money from the Fed keeps some fraction of the funds in reserves, as required by
law, and then loans out the rest. Whoever receives those loans will spend them
somewhere, perhaps at a car dealership or a department store. That money
eventually ends up in other banks, which will keep some funds in reserve and
then make loans of their own. A move by the Fed to inject $100 million of new
funds into the banking system may ultimately increase the money supply by 10
times as much.
Of course, the Fed chairman does not actually drive a truck to a Citibank
branch to swap cash for bonds. The FOMC can accomplish the same thing using
the bond market (which works just like the stock market, except that bonds are
bought and sold). Bond traders working on behalf of the Fed buy bonds from
commercial banks and pay for them with newly created money—funds that
simply did not exist twenty minutes earlier. (Presumably the banks selling their
bonds will be those with the most opportunities to make new loans.) The Fed
will continue to buy bonds with new money, a process called open market
operations, until the target federal funds rate has been reached.
Obviously what the Fed giveth, the Fed can take away. The Federal Reserve
can raise interest rates by doing the opposite of everything we’ve just discussed.
The FOMC would vote to raise the discount rate and/or the target fed funds rate
and issue an order to sell bonds from its portfolio to commercial banks. As banks
give up lendable funds in exchange for bonds, the money supply shrinks. Money
that might have been loaned out to consumers and businesses is parked in bonds
instead. Interest rates go up, and anything purchased with borrowed capital
becomes more expensive. The cumulative effect is slower economic growth.
The mechanics of the Fed’s handiwork should not obscure the big picture. The
Federal Reserve’s mandate is to facilitate a sustainable pace of economic
growth. But let’s clarify how difficult that job really is. First, we are only
guessing at the rate at which the economy can expand without igniting inflation.
One debate among economists is over whether or not computers and other kinds
of information technology have made Americans significantly more productive.
If so, as Mr. Greenspan suggested during his tenure, then the economy’s
potential growth rate may have gone up. If not, as other economists have argued
convincingly, then the old speed limit still applies. Obviously it is hard to abide
by a speed limit that is not clearly posted.
But that is only the first challenge. The Fed must also reckon what kind of
impact a change in interest rates will have and how long it will take. Will a
quarter-point rate cut cause twelve people to buy new PT Cruisers in Des
Moines or 421? When? Next week or six months from now? Meanwhile, the Fed
has the most control over short-term interest rates, which may or may not move
in the same direction as long-term rates. Why can’t Ben Bernanke work his
magic on long-term rates, too? Because long-term rates do not depend on the
money supply today; they depend on what the markets predict money supply
(relative to demand) will be ten, twenty, or even thirty years from now. Ben
Bernanke has no control over the money supply in 2015. Also remember that
while the Fed is trying to use monetary policy to hit a particular economic target,
Congress may be doing things with fiscal policy—government decisions on
taxes and spending—that have a different effect entirely (or have the same
effect, causing Fed policy to overshoot).
So let’s stick with our speed limit analogy and recap what exactly the Fed is
charged with doing. The Fed must facilitate a rate of economic growth that is
neither too fast nor too slow. Bear in mind: (1) We do not know the economy’s
exact speed limit. (2) Both the accelerator and the brake operate with a lag,
meaning that neither works immediately when we press on it. Instead, we have
to wait a while for a response—anywhere from a few weeks to a few years, but
not with any predictable pattern. An inexperienced driver might press
progressively harder on the gas, wondering why nothing is happening (and
enduring all kinds of public assaults on his pathetically slow driving), only to
find the car screaming out of control nine months later. (3) Monetary and fiscal
policy affect the economy independently, so while the Fed is gently applying the
brake, Congress and the president may be jumping up and down on the
accelerator. Or the Fed may tap on the accelerator ever so slightly only to have
Congress weigh it down with a brick. (4) Last, there is the obstacle course of
world events—a financial collapse here, a spike in the price of oil there. Think of
the Fed as always driving in unfamiliar terrain with a map that’s at least ten
years out of date.
Bob Woodward’s biography of Alan Greenspan was titled Maestro. In the
1990s, as the American economy roared through its longest expansion in
economic history, Mr. Greenspan was given credit for his “Goldilocks” approach
to monetary policy—doing everything just right. That reputation has since come
Dostları ilə paylaş: |