Party Congress in early
2006.
What, then, can China learn from developed countries in the sphere of income insurance?
When discussing this issue, it should be noted that in their early phases of economic
development, today’s rich countries relied mainly on (modest) safety nets – rather than on
arrangements for income protection (i.e., benefits in some proportion to previous
earnings). It was only after those countries had become rather well off, mainly after World
War II, that comprehensive arrangements for income protection (social insurance) became
common.
132
Moreover, it was not until the 1970s that these arrangements became so
generous that aggregate social transfers in Western Europe reached the interval of 20-30
percent of GDP. As a result, during the early phase of building up income security in
today’s developed countries, previous informal systems of income transfer – connected
with relatives, or run by so-called “friendly societies” – survived until new, more formal
transfer systems had acquired solid financial and administrative bases.
133
So much for lessons from the
early
development of income insurance among today’s
developed countries. Some experiences from
contemporary,
highly ambitious systems of
income protection in these countries are also of interest for China (as well as for other
developing countries). I refer, for instance, to the importance that such systems are
financially robust to various types of “unfavorable” exogenous shocks, such as in
demography, productivity growth and macroeconomic instability. One conceivable way
of achieving this could be to make the benefits automatically contingent on the
development of certain variables such as the rate of growth of the tax base, the number of
131
Such experiments are underway in eleven provinces, with the explicit (ultimate) purpose of
eliminating the differences in income security between urban and rural areas (
China Daily
, Nov. 2.
2005).
132
Germany under Bismarck introduced social insurance for industrial workers earlier than other
countries, and the United States built up universal social security, mainly in the form of old-age pensions
as early as the mid-1930s.
133
This point is developed in Lindbeck (2002).
66
individuals above retirement age, and the number of individuals living on various benefit
systems (Lindbeck, 2006). Indeed, social insurance in some developed countries is today
heading in this direction. The basic idea is to relieve politicians from the necessity to take
unpopular policy measures from time to time for the purpose of guaranteeing the financial
sustainability of various social insurance systems.
Another lesson from developed countries is that the consequences of income-security
arrangements and redistribution policies for economic efficiency and economic growth
depend crucially on exactly how the arrangements are designed. Therefore, it does not
make sense to ask whether there is a trade-off between income security and redistribution,
on one hand, and economic efficiency and growth, on the other hand,
without first
specifying how the arrangements of income security are actually designed
. For instance,
undesired disincentives effects of the taxes required to finance such systems may be
mitigated by establishing a rather tight “link” between contributions and benefits for the
individual – although this naturally reduces the redistributional effects across individuals.
Moral hazard in the connection with various benefit systems (such as increased leisure
financed by the general tax payer) may also be mitigated by making benefits distinctly
lower than the after-tax wage. Otherwise, there is a risk that individuals develop a
gradually more “liberal” interpretation of their rights to live on various types of benefits,
such as unemployment benefits, sickness absence pay, and early retirement benefits. Such
a weakening of attitudes and social norms towards benefit dependency would accentuate
the problem of moral hazard. Indeed, I have hypothesized elsewhere that contemporary
welfare-state problems in several developed countries are partly due to such changes of
attitudes and social norms (Lindbeck, 1995; Lindbeck, Nyberg and Weibull, 1998).
These lessons from developed countries may seem self-evident at first, but experience
shows that they are not easily learned and adhered to. Contemporary experience in several
countries in Western Europe also expose the political difficulties in cutting back the
generosity of welfare-state arrangements even after both experts and many politicians
have become convinced that existing arrangements are not sustainable. It is, therefore,
important that China watches out for problems of disincentives and moral hazard in the
future when expanding its social insurance system – preferably before the problems have
become severe.
|