what kind of Macroprudential Regulation Framework? | Think Tank | European
Parliament
.
[online]
www.europarl.europa.eu.
Available
at:
https://www.europarl.europa.eu/thinktank/en/document/IPOL_STU(2021)662925.
Salehi, M., & Alipour, M. (2010). E-banking in emerging economy: empirical evidence
of Iran.
International Journal of economics and finance
,
2
(1), 201-209.
Schulte, S. R. (2008).
State technology to state of being: The making of the internet
in global popular culture (1980
–2000)
(Doctoral dissertation, The George Washington
University).
Scott, S. V., & Zachariadis, M. (2012). Origins and development of SWIFT, 1973
–
2009.
Business History
,
54
(3), 462-482.
Shamdasani, P., Mukherjee, A., & Malhotra, N. (2008). Antecedents and
consequences of service quality in consumer evaluation of self-service internet
technologies.
The Service Industries Journal
,
28
(1), 117-138.
26
Chapter 2: Digital transformation of the banking system in
Europe
2.1. Digital transformation (DT)
Globally, organisations undergo periods of change for many reasons, such as
growth, resolving internal issues, adapting to external pressures and adopting
additional changes for the future (Kanter, 2003). Organizational change is a double-
edged sword, as it is required for organizational viability but it is found to impact the
workforce negatively and finds resistance (Demerouti et al., 2021: 374). Aravopoulou
(2016: 19) pointed out that organizational change is a broad term that involves
changes to a small or large extent. Organizational development affects both the
internal and external environment of the organization. For this reason, they act as
"drivers" of change and the two types of influences tend to complement each other.
Internal environmental changes in an organisation include new equipment, new
services and products, recruitment of new staff, new structure in the organisation's
operations and change in strategy. That external environmental changes, according
to Child (2015), involve new policies from central authority, social and cultural,
technological, demographic, economic and changes in market forces (Alvesson &
Sveningsson, 2015: 14). The nature of both the internal and external environment,
which is subject to change due to the reason of DT, forces organisations to change
many departments and areas within the organisation, including their strategy,
structure, operations, technology and culture (Andrew & Mohankumar, 2015: 302).
Limerick et al. (1995) defined organizational transformation as a holistic,
ecological, humanistic approach to a radical, revolutionary change in the entire
context of an organizational system. Transformational changes alter the basic
structure, strategy and culture of the organization (including values and norms). It
requires new learning, an innovative culture and effective leadership for successful
implementation of DT. Many studies describe organizational transformation as a
fundamental revolutionary change that occurs in the very structure of the
organization. Furthermore, DT can be used as a tool for organizational development
by encouraging operational structure and competitiveness while transforming the
organization's strategy (Hanelt et al., 2021: 1170).
27
The rapid adoption of new digital technologies and their development over
time has caused huge changes in almost all organisations and across the globe.
These large-scale changes are widely known as DT, where it has been the focus of
many academics and researchers with the development of business research. Vial
(2019: 118) defined DT as a process that aims to improve an entity by inducing
changes in its properties through the combination of information, technologies,
computing, communications and connectivity of these parts. On the other hand, there
are researchers who support the definition of DT as the enormous changes caused
by digital technologies in organizations (Hess et al., 2016).
Hess et al. (2016) highlighted DT for its complex nature and its role in
transforming the business model of the entire industry. DT encompasses the
concepts of "process alignment and culture transformation" (Gong & Ribiere, 2021:
2). According to these changes, improvements in productivity, performance and
profitability of an organization can be achieved. Although Chatzopoulos and Weber
(2021: 75) reported that DT improves organizations in areas such as customer
experience and operations, which Westerman et al. (2014) agree with, however the
latter added that success could only be achieved at the individual, organizational and
financial levels if strong leadership skills are used to transform the organization and
its culture in conjunction with strengthening the areas of business development.
Parise et al. (2016: 2) focused on the consumer-focused definition of Digital
Transformation, in which digital technologies are used to enhance the customer
experience. While Horlacher & Hess (2016: 5133) pointed out that DT occurs when
values and revenues are created due to digital technologies. On the other hand,
Lundberg et al. (2020: 4347) described DT as "innovations" that provide changes in
"structures, practices, values and beliefs". van Tonder et al. (2020: 116) defined the
areas that were transformed during the transformation process that include business
models, products, services, operations, processes, networks, skills, new talent
development and culture production. While, Gurbaxani et al. (2019: 209) added that
transformation can occur through vision development, strategy and change in the
structure of the organization.
It is necessary to distinguish between digitisation and DT. First, the former
can be achieved through the application of technological methods, while the latter
requires radical and holistic changes (Fischer at al., 2020: 2). Second, although each
of the two terms has a different meaning, some authors use the two terms
interchangeably (Legner at al. 2017: 3). Digital innovation is considered the cause of
digital penetration (Rodríguez-Abitia & Bribiesca-Correa, 2021: 1). However, DT is
considered the change process caused by both digital penetration and digital
28
innovation. At the same time, DT is also considered as a result of digital innovation
(Skog et al., 2018: 432).
According to Tilson et al. (2010: 2), digital technologies have paved the way
for digitisation, digital innovation, penetration and digital media. Due to the use of
digital technologies, organizations must simultaneously make changes at multiple
levels, including its strategy and culture (Ismail et al., 2017).
The implementation of digital transformation is linked to strategies where
organisations seek to set and redefine key objectives that are in line with increased
customer expectations. Essentially, companies implementing digital transformation
can innovate and optimise their operations by upgrading their business model. In
addition, the culture of the organisation is directly linked to digital transformation, as it
can accelerate its implementation or, conversely, be a problem and a cause of delay.
The consumers themselves also play a key role in the implementation of digital
transformation, as digital transformation comes to be linked to their real needs, as
well as to the requirements they express. Finally, it should be mentioned that through
the applications of digital transformation, the levels of interaction between the human
resources and the organization are enhanced, as well as between the customers and
the organization itself (Ministry of Digital Governance, n.d.).
2.2. The cost-benefit regulation on the traditional banking
operations
Regulation ideas have been founded on two basic paradigms: public interest
and private interest theories. The assumption behind public interest regulatory
theories is that regulators have sufficient knowledge and enforcement powers to
successfully promote the public interest. Thus, regulation is provided in response to
public demand for the correction of inequitable or inefficient market processes
(Baumol, 2004). The implication is that regulations are designed to serve society as a
whole rather than popular vested interests.
According to the public interest viewpoint, regulation supports the efficient
operation of banks by simply avoiding market failures for the benefit of larger civil
society (Whynes and Bowles, 1981). Because regulators are regarded as neutral
arbiters, they would not be hampered by information market failures, and they could
more easily package information to establish the point at which the marginal cost of
29
intervention equals the marginal social benefits (Asch, 1988). As a result, the public
interest would be served if the banking system allocated resources in a socially
optimal manner that maximizes production while minimizing variations, i.e.
maximizes social welfare. In contrast, the private interest theory of regulation is more
skeptical of regulators' motivations and behavior, viewing regulation as socially
ineffective. The regulators are supposed to be under-informed about cost, demand,
quality, and other aspects of corporate behavior. They are also vulnerable to
regulatory capture by advocacy or special interest groups. As a result, when it comes
to controlling enterprises or societal activities, they can only do it imperfectly, if at all
(Den Hertog, 2010: 20).
2.2.1. Capital Requirements and Cost Efficiency
Bank capital adequacy is critical in mitigating financial insolvency. Several
studies have found that tight capital requirements improve bank cost-efficiency
(Haque and Brown, 2017: 7; Chortareas et al. 2012: 297). Other studies, on the other
hand, have claimed that strict financial market regulation has the potential to harm
banks' performance by prohibiting them from enjoying economies of scale and scope
through a more diverse variety of banking products or a bigger scale of operations
(Barth et al., 2013: 26-27). In this situation, regulations may result in inefficient
resource allocation; thus, deregulation allows and pushes banks to use more efficient
manufacturing practices (Claessens & Laeven, 2004: 5).
According to Anginer, Demirguc-Kunt, and Zhu (2014: 21), prudential capital
requirements appear to have a favorable influence on bank stability in banking
sectors with (1) relatively weak supervision and monitoring and (2) underdeveloped
institutions. Furthermore, he established that banks in transition nations saw a surge
in demand for bank loans during the research period because the majority of those
countries had seen sustained growth and low inflation rates for over two decades.
However, the presence of regulatory capital requirements has constrained banks'
ability to develop.
When controlling for other supervisory and regulatory policies, Barth et al.
(2004) discover that, while stringent capital requirements are associated with fewer
nonperforming loans, capital stringency is not robustly linked with banking sector
stability, development, or bank performance (measured with overhead and margin
ratios). Furthermore, in determining whether greater capital requirements are
worthwhile, D’Erasmo (2018: 5) discovered that higher capital requirements cause
30
major banks to grow larger, placing pressure on small banks to combine or collapse.
As huge banks' market clout develops, they extract higher profits by hiking lending
rates, which tightens credit and depresses the economy's productivity. Furthermore,
fewer fail while taking more risks because their charter value is higher under the
tighter capital requirements.
2.2.2. Liquidity Requirement and Cost Efficiency
Liquidity is crucial to the stability of the banking system, given that it
represents the ability to fund assets and satisfy obligations when they fall due.
According to Ryan et al. (2014: 28), tougher liquidity laws would compel banks to
change both their asset and liability organizations in order to meet these new criteria.
This suggests that their policies tend towards improving their share of high-quality
liquid assets and funding from more stable non-financial deposits while at the same
time, strive to lower the short-term intra-financial loans share and short-term
wholesale funding. Corporate lending rates and interbank funding costs are also
influenced by the liquidity ratio. Bonner and Eijffinger (2012) discovered that Dutch
banks who fell short of their liquidity targets did not impose a higher interest rate on
business loans. Furthermore, the banks paid higher interest rates on unsecured
interbank loans, despite the fact that this regulatory information was not made public.
2.2.3. Interest Rate and Cost Efficiency
According to Eregha (2010: 41), interest rates have a favorable impact on
domestic loan demand in the short term but a detrimental impact in the long run.
Increases in actual lending rates may not have an immediate impact on credit
demand; nevertheless, in the long run, they may lead to a decrease in credit demand
and vice versa. As a result, the possibility that interest rate regulation is an
unproductive policy choice emerges. According to Maimbo and Gallegos (2014: 23),
interest rate caps are ineffective at addressing the underlying causes of high rates,
such as a lack of market competition, market inefficiency, large fiscal deficits, and
legal bottlenecks that prevent customers from switching banks, and they introduce
additional distortions into the system as banks attempt to circumvent caps.
31
2.2.4. Quality of Funding and Cost Efficiency
According to Arnould et al. (2021: 2), excessive funding costs caused by
bank-specific vulnerabilities can erode banks' revenues and deplete banks' capital
buffers in bad times or slow their build-up in good times. This means that excessive
funding costs caused by bank vulnerabilities might harm banks' ability to absorb
macroeconomic shocks and jeopardize the banking sector's overall stability.
Furthermore, Arnould et al. (2021: 11) believe that if increased funding costs are
carried through to higher lending rates, the real economy will suffer by decreasing
demand for new lending, causing deleveraging, and resulting in weaker economic
activity. Ellis and Flannery (1992: 485) demonstrated the relationship between capital
levels and interest rates. They give empirical evidence that lower capital levels are
connected with higher interest rates on uninsured deposits.
2.2.5. Security Market Regulation and Cost Efficiency
The creation of an informationally and financially efficient market is aided by
the security market. According to Avgouleas and Cullen (2014: 8), countries with
underdeveloped capital markets and inefficient legal frameworks make market
discipline an inadequate instrument for improving banking sector efficiency.
Furthermore, a lack of openness in financial transactions and poor information quality
cause principal/agency relationships to fail, resulting in severe restrictions in
comprehending and assessing risks, rendering traditional models of corporate
governance useless. In opposite, Barth et al. (2013) believe that regulatory scrutiny
has been severely influencing the efficiency of the banks by imposing expenses,
including higher origination standards, slower loan growth, compliance costs and
inefficiencies.
2.2.6. Bank size and Cost Efficiency
Bank size, which is frequently assessed by total assets, determines both the
scope of activity and the type of clients it serves. Huge banks, for example, have a
customer that is more stable, such as governments, large enterprises, and
international corporations. Small banks, on the other hand, primarily serve
disadvantaged and low-income households and their microenterprises. Larger banks
32
are more efficient, according to Tecles and Tabak (2010: 1592). On the contrary, Isik
and Hassan (2002: 731).
2.2.7. Macroeconomic Environment and Cost Efficiency
Economic growth increases cost-efficiency, whereas inflation increases cost-
inefficiency. The negative relationship between GDP growth and cost inefficiencies is
that increased disposable income leads to increased demand for goods and services
produced by enterprises. Increased sales would, in turn, enhance enterprises' and
consumers' debt service capabilities, resulting in a decrease in non-performing loans.
Rinaldi and Sanchis-Arellano (2006: 6) discovered that rising inflation impairs the
performance of the bank loan portfolio, implying a positive (negative) link between
inflation and cost inefficiencies. In studies to capture the effect of the macroeconomic
environment, inflation and GDP growth rate have been utilized (Osoro & Kiplangat,
2020: 10).
Mulidy (2021) estimated the Bank regulation - Cost inefficiency nexus at
Industry-level. According to the findings, rigorous capital requirements have a
favorable and statistically significant influence on bank cost efficiency. This finding
indicates that banks' cost-cutting behavior is positively related to capital-requirement
tightening. The findings are consistent with those of Barth et al. (2013), Haque and
Brown (2017) and Chortareas et al. (2012), who found that rigorous capital
requirements improve bank cost efficiency.
Coefficient
T-ratio
Constant
16.387
5.00
Capital adequacy
-3.9519
-4.21
Liquidity Ratio
5.4464
9.60
Interest Rate
-0.00005
-1.36
Quality of Funding
-0.31717
-1.31
Size
-0.93942
-2.89
Security Market Dummy
0.67314
1.11
GDP Growth Rate
-18.9698
-1.90
Inflation rate
-4.0909
-1.46
Table 1 Bank Regulation - Cost Inefficiency Nexus at Industry-Level (Mulindi, 2021)
According to Cambis (2012), since the 1960s and 1970s, with the seminal
work of Phelps, Friedman, and Lucas, inflation expectations have been a central
33
factor in models of inflationary dynamics, and they play a crucial role in New
Keynesian dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) models used to inform
and evaluate monetary policy. In many inflation models utilized by central banks,
inflation is driven by three primary factors: some measure of a resource utilization
gap (such as the output gap or unemployment rate gap) or marginal cost of
production; lagged inflation, which captures the inertia in the inflation process; and
inflation expectations. According to Coibion, Gorodnichenko, and Ropele (2019),
enterprises do base pricing decisions on their inflation forecasts, and their research
demonstrates that firms boost prices in response to rising inflation expectations.
Additionally, the OECD Composite Leading Indicators (CLIs), which are
designed to predict economic activity reversals over the next six to nine months,
continue to indicate a deteriorating picture in the majority of the world's largest
nations. The CLIs continue to foresee a loss of growth momentum in the majority of
significant OECD nations, as they are weighed down by historically high inflation,
poor consumer confidence, and falling share market indexes. The OECD composite
leading indicators are cyclical indicators based on a variety of forward-looking
measures, including order books, building permits, confidence indicators, long-term
interest rates, and new vehicle registrations, among others (Cambis, 2022).
34
References
Alvesson, M., & Sveningsson, S. (2015).
Dostları ilə paylaş: |