and demand curves and
fully informed rational choice, and capitalism meant
simply market exchange. Notwithstanding this grounding in economic theory,
Lösch showed that geography did matter, in two ways. First, is morphogenesis;
economic mechanisms can produce a spatially differentiated economic landscape,
even when the geographical backcloth is undifferentiated (i.e. an unbounded
uniform plain). Second, space trumps economic theory. Perfect
competition is
impossible on a uniform plain; rather imperfect competition prevails, with the
implication that capitalists make non-zero profits (unlike the zero profits of stan-
dard microeconomic theory), reducing consumer welfare. Nevertheless, competi-
tion minimized these reductions, as well as differences
between the real incomes
of the most and least well off consumers (those closest and farthest, respectively,
from producers).
At the macroeconomic scale, and under the assumptions of mainstream
economic theory, regional scientists showed that unrestricted mobility of labor,
capital, know-how and commodities also generate spatial equilibrium outcomes that
tendentially minimize profits and equalize economic
welfare across regions for
the average consumer. Together, these results had strong normative implications.
As Lösch (1954: 4) put it: ‘The question of the best location is far more digni-
fied than that of the actual location’. Inequalities in livelihood chances, defined
here in terms of consumer welfare, could be reduced through the proliferation
of
market rationality, with the state intervening to address market failures due to
the spatial nature of public goods. Philosophically, this approach aligned itself
with the precepts of positivism, insisting on logical rigor and mathematical
precision, and on observation as the independent arbiter of theory.
Dostları ilə paylaş: